July 2007 C:/Pfusch/ShadEconomyCorruption_July2007.doc Revised version Shadow Economies and Corruption all over the World: New Estimates for 145 Countries by Friedrich Schneider*) Abstract: Estimations of the shadow economies for 145 countries, including developing, transition and highly developed OECD economies over 1999 to 2005 are presented. The average size of the shadow economy (as a percent of "official" GDP) in 2004/05 in 96 developing countries is 36.7%, in 25 transition countries 38.8% and in 21 OECD countries 14.8%. An increased burden of taxation and social security contributions, combined with a labour market regulation are the driving forces of the shadow economy. Furthermore, the results show that the shadow economy reduces corruption in high income countries, but increases corruption in low income countries. Finally, the various estimation methods are discussed and critically evaluated. JEL-class.: O17, O5, D78, H2, H11, H26. Keywords: shadow economy of 145 countries, tax burden, tax moral, quality of state institutions, regulation, DYMIMIC and other estimation methods *) Professor of Economics, Dr. DDr.h.c. Friedrich Schneider, Department of Economics, Johannes Kepler University of Linz, A-4040 Linz-Auhof, Austria. Phone: 0043-732-24688210, Fax: -8209. E-mail: friedrich.schneider@jku.at, http://www.econ.jku.at/Schneider. 31.07.07, C:\ShadEconomyCorruption_July2007.doc 1 Contents 1 Introduction .......................................................................................................................3 2 Some Theoretical Considerations about the Shadow Economy....................................4 2.1 Defining the Shadow Economy ................................................................................................. 4 2.2 The Main Causes of the Shadow Economy ............................................................................... 6 2.2.1 2.2.2 2.2.3 2.2.4 2.2.5 3 Tax and Social Security Contribution Burdens ............................................................................... 6 Intensity of Regulations .................................................................................................................. 7 Public Sector Services..................................................................................................................... 8 Public Opinion about the Shadow Economy................................................................................... 8 Summary of the Main Causes of the Shadow Economy ............................................................... 13 The Size of the Shadow Economy for 145 Countries ...................................................14 3.1 Econometric Results ............................................................................................................... 14 3.2 The Size of the Shadow Economies for 145 Countries for 1999/2000 to 2004/2005.............. 21 3.2.1 3.2.2 3.2.3 3.2.4 3.2.5 Developing Countries.................................................................................................................... 21 Transition Countries...................................................................................................................... 25 Highly developed OECD-Countries.............................................................................................. 26 South West Pacific Islands............................................................................................................ 27 Communist Countries.................................................................................................................... 28 4 Corruption and the Shadow Economy: Substitutes or Compliments?)......................29 5 Summary and Conclusions .............................................................................................33 6 Appendix 1: Methods to Estimate the Size of the Shadow Economy: The DYMIMIC and Currency Demand Approach ........................................................................................35 6.1 6.1.1 6.1.2 6.2 6.2.1 6.2.2 6.2.3 6.2.4 6.2.5 Direct Approaches .................................................................................................................. 35 Survey Method .............................................................................................................................. 35 Tax Auditing Method .................................................................................................................... 38 Indirect Approaches................................................................................................................ 39 The Discrepancy between National Expenditure and Income Statistics ....................................... 39 The Discrepancy between the Official and Actual Labour Force ................................................. 40 The Transactions Approach .......................................................................................................... 40 The Currency Demand Approach.................................................................................................. 41 The Physical Input (Electricity Consumption) Method................................................................. 44 6.3 The Model Approach .............................................................................................................. 46 6.4 Summarizing the Critical Remarks ......................................................................................... 49 6.5 The Size and Development of the Shadow Economies of 145 Countries over 1999/2000 to 2004/2005 .......................................................................................................................................... 50 7 Appendix 2: Definition of the variables and data sources ...........................................54 8 References.........................................................................................................................57 31.07.07, C:\ShadEconomyCorruption_July2007.doc 2 1 Introduction As corruption and shadow economic activities are a fact of life around the world, most societies attempt to control these activities through various measures like punishment, prosecution, economic growth or education. To gather information about the extent of corruption and the shadow economy and its relationship or who is engaged in corrupt and/or underground activities, the frequency with which these activities are occurring and their magnitude of them, is crucial for making effective and efficient decisions regarding the allocations of a country’s resources in this area. Unfortunately, it is very difficult to get accurate information about the relationship between corruption and shadow economy activities on the goods and labour market, because all individuals engaged in these activities wish not to be identified. Hence, doing research in these two areas can be considered as a scientific passion for knowing the unknown. Although substantial literature1) exists on single aspects of the hidden or shadow economy and a comprehensive survey has been written by Schneider (the author of this paper) and Enste (2000), the subject is still quite controversial2) as there are disagreements about the definition of shadow economy activities, the estimation procedures and the use of their estimates in economic analysis and policy aspects3). Nevertheless around the world, there are some indications for an increase of the shadow economy but little is known about the development and the size of the shadow economies in transition, developing and developed countries over the latest period 1999 to 2005. Hence, the goal of this paper is threefold: (i) to undertake the challenging task of estimating the shadow economy for 145 countries all over the world4) (ii) to provide some insights into 1) The literature about the "shadow", "underground", "informal", "second", "cash-" or "parallel", economy is increasing. Various topics, on how to measure it, its causes, its effect on the official economy are analyzed. See for example, survey type publications by Frey and Pommerehne (1984); Thomas (1992); Loayza (1996); Pozo (1996); Lippert and Walker (1997); Schneider (1994a, 1994b, 1997, 1998a, 2003, 2005, 2007); Johnson, Kaufmann, and Shleifer (1997), Johnson, Kaufmann and Zoido-Lobatón (1998a, 1998b); Belev (2003); Gerxhani (2003) and Pedersen (2003). For an overall survey of the global evidence of the size of the shadow economy see Bajada and Schneider (2005), Schneider and Enste (2000, 2002, 2006) and Alm, Martinez and Schneider (2004), and Kazemier (2005a) 2) Compare e.g. in the Economic Journal, vol. 109, no. 456, June 1999 the feature "controversy: on the hidden economy”. 3) Compare the different opinions of Tanzi (1999), Thomas (1999), Giles (1999a,b) and Pedersen (2003), and Janisch and Brümmerhoff (2005). 4) This paper focuses on the size and development of the shadow economy for countries and does not show any disaggregated values for specific regions. Lately some first studies were undertaken to measure the size of the 31.07.07, C:\ShadEconomyCorruption_July2007.doc 3 the main causes of the shadow economy, and (iii) to explore the relationship between shadow and corruption. In section 2 an attempt is made to define the shadow economy and some theoretical considerations about the reasons why it is increasing. Section 3 presents the econometric estimation results and the calculation of the size of the shadow economy in 145 countries in the period 1999/2000 to 2004/05. In section 4 two hypotheses about the relationship between the shadow economy and corruption are derived and some empirical results are shown. In section 5 a summary is given and some policy conclusions are drawn. Finally in the three appendices (chapters 6, 7 and 8) the various methods to estimate the shadow economy are presented and critically evaluated, a definition of the variables and data sources are given, and the descriptive statistics of the variables are shown. 2 Some Theoretical Considerations about the Shadow Economy 2.1 Defining the Shadow Economy Most authors trying to measure the shadow economy face the difficulty of how to define it. One commonly used working definition is all currently unregistered economic activities that contribute to the officially calculated (or observed) Gross National Product5). Smith (1994, p. 18) defines it as "market-based production of goods and services, whether legal or illegal, that escapes detection in the official estimates of GDP." Or to put it in another way, one of the broadest definitions of it includes…"those economic activities and the income derived from them that circumvent or otherwise avoid government regulation, taxation or observation"6). As these definitions still leave open a lot of questions, table 2.1 is helpful for developing a better feeling for what could be a reasonable consensus definition of the underground (or shadow) economy. From table 2.1, it becomes clear that a broad definition of the shadow economy includes unreported income from the production of legal goods and services, either from monetary or shadow economy as well as the "grey” or "shadow” labour force for urban regions or states (e.g. California). Compare e.g. Marcelli, Pastor and Joassart (1999), Marcelli (2004), Chen (2004), Williams (2004a, b, 2005a, b, 2006), Williams and Windebank (1999, 2001a, b), Flaming, Haydamack, and Jossart (2005) and Alderslade, Talmage and Freeman (2006), and Brueck, Haisten-DeNew and Zimmermann (2006). 5) This definition is used for example, by Feige (1989, 1994), Schneider (1994a, 2003, 2005, 2007) and Frey and Pommerehne (1984). Do-it-yourself activities are not included. For estimates of the shadow economy and the doit-yourself activities for Germany see Karmann (1986, 1990), and Buehn, Karmann and Schneider (2007). 6) This definition is taken from Del’Anno (2003), Del’Anno and Schneider (2004) and Feige (1989); see also Thomas (1999), Fleming, Roman and Farrell (2000). 31.07.07, C:\ShadEconomyCorruption_July2007.doc 4 barter transactions – and so includes all economic activities that would generally be taxable were they reported to the state (tax) authorities. In this paper the following more narrow definition of the shadow economy is used7). The shadow economy includes all market-based legal production of goods and services that are deliberately concealed from public authorities for the following reasons: (1) to avoid payment of income, value added or other taxes, (2) to avoid payment of social security contributions, (3) to avoid having to meet certain legal labour market standards, such as minimum wages, maximum working hours, safety standards, etc., and (4) to avoid complying with certain administrative procedures, such as completing statistical questionnaires or other administrative forms. Hence, in this paper, I will not deal with typical underground, economic (classical crime) activities, which are all illegal actions that fit the characteristics of classical crimes like burglary, robbery, drug dealing, etc. I also exclude the informal household economy which consists of all household services and production. This paper also does not focus on tax evasion or tax compliance, because it would get too long, and moreover tax evasion is a different subject, where already a lot of research has been undertaken8). Table 2.1: A Taxonomy of Types of Underground Economic Activities1) Type of Activity Illegal Activities Monetary Transactions Non Monetary Transactions Trade with stolen goods; drug dealing and manufacturing; prostitution; gambling; smuggling; fraud; etc. Barter of drugs, stolen goods, smuggling etc. Produce or growing drugs for own use. Theft for own use. Tax Evasion Tax Avoidance Employee discounts, fringe benefits Tax Evasion Tax Avoidance Unreported income Barter of legal All do-itfrom selfservices and yourself work employment; wages, and neighbour goods salaries and assets help from unreported work related to legal services and goods 1) Structure of the table is taken from Lippert and Walker (1997, p. 5) with additional remarks. Legal Activities 7) Compare also the excellent discussion of the definition of the shadow economy in Pedersen (2003, pp.13-19) and Kazemier (2005a) who use a similar one. 8) Compare, e.g. the survey of Andreoni, Erard and Feinstein (1998) and the paper by Kirchler, Maciejovsky and Schneider (2002). 31.07.07, C:\ShadEconomyCorruption_July2007.doc 5 2.2 2.2.1 The Main Causes of the Shadow Economy Tax and Social Security Contribution Burdens In almost all studies9) it has been ascertained that the overall tax and social security contribution burdens are among the main causes for the existence of the shadow economy. Since taxes affect labour-leisure choices, and also stimulate labour supply in the shadow economy, the distortion of the overall tax burden is a major concern for economists. The bigger the difference between the total cost of labour in the official economy and the after-tax earnings (from work), the greater is the incentive to avoid this difference and to work in the shadow economy. Since this difference depends broadly on the social security burden/payments and the overall tax burden, they latter are key features of the existence and the increase of the shadow economy. But even major tax reforms with major tax rate deductions will not lead to a substantial decrease of the shadow economy10). Such reforms will only be able to stabilize the size of the shadow economy and avoid a further increase. Social networks and personal relationships, the high profit from irregular activities and associated investments in real and human capital are strong ties which prevent people from transferring to the official economy. For Canada, Spiro (1993) found similar reactions of people facing an increase in indirect taxes (VAT, GST). This fact makes it even more difficult for politicians to carry out major reforms because they may not gain a lot from them. Empirical results of the influence of the tax burden on the shadow economy is provided in the studies of Schneider (1994b, 2000, 2004, 2005) and Johnson, Kaufmann and Zoido-Lobatón (1998a, 1998b); they all found statistically significant evidence for the influence of taxation on the shadow economy. This strong influence of indirect and direct taxation on the shadow economy is further demonstrated by discussing empirical results in the case of Austria and the Scandinavian countries. For Austria the driving force for the shadow economy activities is the direct tax burden (including social security payments); it has the biggest influence, followed by the intensity of regulation and complexity of the tax system. A similar result has been found by Schneider (1986) for the Scandinavian countries (Denmark, Norway and Sweden). In all three countries various tax variables: average direct tax rate, average total tax rate 9) See Thomas (1992); Lippert and Walker (1997); Schneider (1994a,b, 1997, 1998a,b, 2000, 2003b, 2005, 2007); Johnson, Kaufmann, and Zoido-Lobatón (1998a,1998b); Tanzi (1999); Giles (1999a); Mummert and Schneider (2001); Giles and Tedds (2002) and Dell’Anno (2003), just to quote a few recent ones. 10) See Schneider (1994b, 1998b) a similar result of the effects of a major tax reform in Austria on the shadow economy. Schneider shows that a major reduction in the direct tax burden did not lead to a major reduction in the shadow economy. Because legal tax avoidance was abolished and other factors, like regulations, were not changed; hence for a considerable part of the tax payers the actual tax and regulation burden remained 31.07.07, C:\ShadEconomyCorruption_July2007.doc 6 (indirect and direct tax rate) and marginal tax rates have the expected positive effect (on currency demand) and are highly statistically significant. These findings are supported by studies of Kirchgaessner (1983, 1984) for Germany, and by Klovland (1984) for Norway, and Sweden, too. In this study an attempt will be made to investigate the influence of the direct and indirect tax burden as well as the social security payments on the shadow economy for developing, transition and highly developed countries over the period 1999 to 2005. 2.2.2 Intensity of Regulations Increased intensity of regulations is another important factor which reduces the freedom (of choice) for individuals engaged in the official economy11). One can think of labour market regulations, trade barriers, and labour restrictions for foreigners. Johnson, Kaufmann, and Zoido-Lobatón (1998b) find significant overall empirical evidence of the influence of (labour) regulations on the shadow economy; and the impact is clearly described and theoretically derived in other studies, e.g. for Germany (Deregulation Commission 1990/91). Regulations lead to a substantial increase in labour costs in the official economy. But since most of these costs can be shifted to the employees, these costs provide another incentive to work in the shadow economy, where they can be avoided. Empirical evidence supporting the model of Johnson, Kaufmann, and Shleifer (1997), which predicts, inter alia, that countries with more general regulation of their economies tend to have a higher share of the unofficial economy in total GDP, is found in their empirical analysis. They conclude that it is the enforcement of regulation which is the key factor for the burden levied on firms and individuals, and not the overall extent of regulation - mostly not enforced - which drives firms into the shadow economy. Friedman, Johnson, Kaufmann and Zoido-Lobaton (1999) reach a similar conclusion. In their study every available measure of regulation is significantly correlated with the share of the unofficial economy and the estimated sign of the relationship is unambiguous: more regulation is correlated with a larger shadow economy. These findings demonstrate that governments should put more emphasis on improving enforcement of laws and regulations, rather than increasing their number. Some governments, however, prefer this policy option (more regulations and laws), when trying to reduce the shadow economy, mostly because it leads to an increase in power for the bureaucrats and to a higher rate of employment in the public sector. unchanged. 11) See for a (social) psychological, theoretical foundation of this feature, Brehm (1966, 1972), and for a (first) 31.07.07, C:\ShadEconomyCorruption_July2007.doc 7 2.2.3 Public Sector Services An increase of the shadow economy can lead to reduced state revenues which in turn reduce the quality and quantity of publicly provided goods and services. Ultimately, this can lead to an increase in the tax rates for firms and individuals in the official sector, quite often combined with a deterioration in the quality of the public goods (such as the public infrastructure) and of the administration, with the consequence of even stronger incentives to participate in the shadow economy. Johnson, Kaufmann, and Zoido-Lobatón (1998a/b) present a simple model of this relationship. Their findings show that smaller shadow economies appear in countries with higher tax revenues if achieved by lower tax rates, fewer laws and regulations and less bribery facing enterprises. Countries with a better rule of law, which is financed by tax revenues, also have smaller shadow economies. Transition countries have higher levels of regulation leading to a significantly higher incidence of bribery, higher effective taxes on official activities and a large discretionary regulatory framework and consequently a higher shadow economy. Their overall conclusion is that "wealthier countries of the OECD, as well as some in Eastern Europe, find themselves in the ‘good equilibrium’ of relatively low tax and regulatory burden, sizeable revenue mobilization, good rule of law and corruption control, and a [relatively] small unofficial economy. By contrast, a number of countries in Latin American and the former Soviet Union exhibit characteristics consistent with a ‘bad equilibrium’: tax and regulatory discretion and burden on the firm is high, the rule of law is weak, and there is a high incidence of bribery and a relatively high share of activities in the unofficial economy." (Johnson, Kaufmann and Zoido-Lobatón 1998a p. I). First results of the influence of corruption on the shadow economy and vice versa are reported in chapter 4 of this section. 2.2.4 Public Opinion about the Shadow Economy The perception of citizens/voters about the shadow economy and their (moral) reaction to this phenomenon is also an important factor, i.e. under which circumstances people decide to work in the shadow economy. There are a number of empirical studies which investigate the tax morale of people and their attitudes towards the shadow economy12). In this section some results for Germany are shown which clearly demonstrate that people have no bad (moral) feeling when working in the shadow economy. In table 2.2 for the year 2007 it is investigated application to the shadow economy, Pelzmann (1988). 12 Compare Halla and Schneider (2005), Torgler (2002), Torgler and Schneider (2005, 2007), Feld and Frey (2005), and Feld and Larsen (2005). 31.07.07, C:\ShadEconomyCorruption_July2007.doc 8 whether people regularly work in the shadow economy or not. 20.7% of the German respondents say "yes", and 30.8% of the respondents regularly demand shadow economy activities. In table 2.3 some reasons are asked for why shadow economy activities are demanded. The most important result is, one saves money – or shadow economy activities are much cheaper than the official ones. The second most important reason is that tax and social security burden is too high (73% of the respondents) and reason number 3 is that due to the much higher labour costs in the official economy one would not demand these activities. Especially the third answer is interesting, because this result clearly demonstrates that only 22% of the demanded shadow economy activities have substitutive character (i.e. they would be demanded in the official economy if there would be no shadow economy) and 30% of the respondents answer that they would do it themselves. From this survey result one can conclude that roughly 48% of these activities would not take place if there were no shadow economy. In table 2.4 examples of some hourly wage rates of shadow economy activities in Germany are shown and what is surprising here is the huge range of wage rates in the shadow economy, for example the varying "price" for an hour of shadow market work by a painter ranges from € 9 to € 17. Table 2.4 clearly demonstrates also the large difference (a multiplicative factor between 4 and 5) between the wage rates in the shadow economy and in the official one. In table 2.5 important attitudes held by Germans regarding what may be classified as a "Kavaliersdelikt" are shown13). These results convincingly demonstrate for the years 1996 to 2003 that roughly two thirds of the German population treat shadow economy activities as a "Kavalierdelikt", whereas only a third treats a small theft such as "stealing a newspaper from a box", as a "Kavaliersdelikt". In table 2.6 value statements of the German population with respect to the shadow economy are shown, and again, two thirds say that without shadow economy earnings one can not keep the achieved standard of living and only a third of the population asked finds that shadow economy activities lead to great losses of tax revenues and social security payments to the state. What are most amazing in table 2.6 are the attitudes of the German population with respect to punishment of shadow economy activities: only between 9% and 3% of the asked German population questioned are convinced that shadow economy workers should be reported to the authorities and prosecuted! One gets a similarly low figure when asking whether a shadow economy worker is detected, he should be severely punished. Only between 7% and 3% of those asked say, "yes". This clearly shows that there is no bad (moral) feeling about working in the shadow economy among the German population. 13 "Kavaliersdelikte”: in english peccadillos 31.07.07, C:\ShadEconomyCorruption_July2007.doc 9 The results are quite similar for Austria. Table 2.2: Work in the Shadow Economy – Survey Results for 2007 (1) Do you work regularly in the shadow economy? No Yes No answer (2) Do you regularly demand shadow economy activities? Values in percent 77,3 20,7 (25% male, 16% female) 2 Values in percent No Yes 69,2 30,8 (35.4% male, 26.5% female) Representative questionnaire, Germany, January 2007 Source: IDW Koeln, Germany Table 2.3: Reasons for Shadow Economy Activities – Survey Results for Germany, January 2007 Reasons why shadow economy activities are demanded Values in percent (1) One saves money – or they are much cheaper than the official ones 90% (2) The tax and social security burden is much too high 73% (3) Due to the high labour costs in the official economy one would not 68% demand these activities (extreme assumption: no shadow economy – 22% demand in the official economy; 30% do-it-themselves; and 48% no demand at all!) 52% (4) The firms offer them themselves 31% (5) It‘s so easy to get quick and reliable workers Representative questionnaire, Germany, January 2007, Source: IDW Koeln 31.07.07, C:\ShadEconomyCorruption_July2007.doc 10 Table 2.4: Hourly wage rates of shadow economy activities – Survey Results for Germany, 2004 Activity/Type of Town/Area Worker Painter Mechanics Wage rate in the Wage rate in the shadow economy official economy (in (in €) €) Berlin 10 – 17 München 9 – 15 Rhein/Rhur 10 – 12 Hamburg 13 – 23 Berlin 15 – 19 München 15 – 23 Cost of moving Berlin household furniture München and other goods Rhein/Rhur 42 58 300 – 380 400 – 450 1.800 350 – 420 (distance 300km) Representative questionnaire, May 2003, Source: Schneider (2004) Table 2.5: Values/Attitudes of the German population regarding the shadow economy Question: What are "Kavaliersdelikte" (negligible delicts)? Statement To demand activities in the shadow economy To drive a car too fast To undertake shadow economic activities oneself To steal a newspaper from a box Not to send children to school To be dishonest when completing tax declarations Not to go to work (e.g. to skive on a Monday) To drive when drunk German Population (in % Yes) May 1996 May 1998 May 2001 Nov./Dec. 2002 Nov./Dec. 2003 55 64 60 68 67 42 43 44 45 46 36 41 33 36 38 28 29 31 30 28 25 27 24 18 16 22 22 18 - 18 18 17 16 13 12 9 4 7 3 4 Source: Schneider (2004) 31.07.07, C:\ShadEconomyCorruption_July2007.doc 11 Table 2.6: Value Judgements/Attitudes from the German population regarding the Shadow Economy Statement German Population (in % Yes) May May May Nov./Dec. Nov./Dec. 1996 1998 2001 2002 2003 Without shadow economy earnings one cannot keep up the standard of living It‘s the state’s/government’s own fault that the shadow economy is so popular and large, because the tax and social security burden is too high In the last 2-3 years I have taken advantage of shadow economic activities Due to shadow economic activities the state loses a great amount of tax revenues and social security payments In the neighbourhood one can observe a significant number of shadow economic activities I think shadow economy workers should be reported to the authorities and prosecuted If a shadow economy worker is detected he should be punished severely (high financial fines) 62 69 69 70 71 63 67 57 66 67 26 38 34 36 39 29 25 30 28 26 - - 24 28 32 9 4 6 3 3 7 4 5 7 3 Source: Schneider (2004) Table 2.7: A comparison of the size of the German Shadow Economy using the survey and the DYMIMIC-method, year 2006. Shadow Shadow Fictive jobs % share of Economy in Various kinds of shadow economy Economy (full time the overall % of activities/values in bill. equivalent) shadow official Euro millions economy GDP Shadow economy activities from 5.0 – 6.0 117 – 140 2.1 – 2.4 33 – 40 labour (hours worked) + Material (used) 3.0 – 4.0 70 – 90 1.2 – 1.5 20 – 25 + Illegal activities (goods and 4.0 – 5.0 90 – 117 1.5 – 2.1 25 – 33 services) + already in the official GDP 1.0 – 2.0 23 – 45 0.4 – 0.8 7 - 13 included illegal activities Sum (1) to (4) 13.0 – 17.0 300 – 392 5.2 – 6.8 85 – 111 Overall (total) shadow economy 15.0 340 6.0 100 (estimated by the DYMIMIC and calibrated by the currency demand procedure) Source: Enste/Schneider (2006) and own calculations. Finally, in table 2.7, a comparison between the size of the German shadow economy, using the survey and the DYMIMIC method, is undertaken. Also an attempt is made to explain the 31.07.07, C:\ShadEconomyCorruption_July2007.doc 12 quite often observed, large differences using a macro (DYMIMIC) and/or currency demand approach to estimate the size of the German shadow economy; e.g. for 2006, we obtain a value of 15% of “official” GDP. Using the survey method, in which the value added of shadow economy from labour activities is captured, one obtains a value between 5 and 6%14). Hence, there is quite a huge difference. The first difference originates from the survey method, where usually not the total overall value added is asked, but only the value added of shadow economy work. If one adds material, one might come up with another 3-4% and one has to add other illegal activities (prostitution, gambling and totally illegal working firms in the construction sector). Hence, one has to add another 4-5% of the size of these activities measured in per cent of official GDP. Finally, official national account authorities (also in Germany) add (or include) already some shadow economy activities in the “official” GDP, so one has to include another 1-2% black activities to official GDP, which sums up roughly to 15%. One also realizes that if one measures these different kinds of shadow activities in per cent of overall shadow economy activities that shadow economy activities from labour (hours worked) has the bigged size with 33-40%, followed by illegal activities in the shadow economy with a size of 25-35%. Table 2.7 quite nicely demonstrates how the differences between the size of the shadow economy using the survey method and compared with the macro approach DYMIMIC and/or curreny demand can be explained. 2.2.5 Summary of the Main Causes of the Shadow Economy In table 2.7 an overview of a number of empirical studies summarizes the various factors influencing the shadow economy. In table 2.7 two columns are presented, showing the various factors influencing the shadow economy with and without the independent variable, "tax morale". This table clearly demonstrates that the increase of tax and social security contribution burdens is by far most important single contributor to the increase of the shadow economy. This factor does explain some 35–38% or 45–52% of the variance of the shadow economy with and without including the variable "tax morale". The variable tax moral accounts for some 22–25% of the variance of the shadow economy15, and finally there is a third factor, "intensity of state regulation "(mostly for the labour market). In general table 2.7 shows that the independent variables tax and social security burden, followed by variables tax 14) Compare also Figure 5.1, where the values using the survey method by Feld and Larsen (2005) vary between 3–4% of “official” GDP. 15 The importance of this variable with respect to theory and empirical importance is also shown in Feld and Frey (2002, 2002a and 2005), Frey (1997), Torgler (2002) and Torgler and Schneider (2005, 2007) 31.07.07, C:\ShadEconomyCorruption_July2007.doc 13 morale and intensity of state regulations are the three major driving forces of the shadow economy. Table 2.7: Main Causes of the Increase of the shadow economy Factors influencing the shadow economy Influence on the shadow economy (in%) 1) (1) (2) 35-38% 45-52% (2) Intensity of State Regulations 8-10% 10-15% (3) Social Transfers 5-7% 5-8% (4) Specific Labour Market Regulations 5-7% 5-8% (5) Public Sector Services 5-7% 5-8% (6) Tax Morale 22-25% - Overall influence 76-94% 70-90% (1) Increase of the Tax and Social Security Contribution Burdens 1) Average values of 15 studies 2) Average values of empirical results of 28 studies. Source: Schneider (2004) 3 The Size of the Shadow Economy for 145 Countries 3.1 Econometric Results In tables 3.1 to 3.3 the econometric estimations using the DYMIMIC approach (latent estimation approach) are presented for the 96 developing countries, the 28 (25) transition and 3 communist countries and the 21 industrialized (highly developed) OECD-countries of our sample16). This grouping was necessary because the available data is different for these countries. For the 96 developing countries and the 28 transition and communist countries the estimation was done for five different points of time 1999/2000, 2001/02 2002/03, 2003/04 and 2004/05 and for the 21 OECD countries I have eight data points of time 1990/91, 1994/95, 1997/98, 1999/2000, 2001/02, 2002/03, 2003/04 and 2004/05. For the developing 16) The classification which country is a developing country follows the one done by the World Bank (2002) using a benchmark per capita income of USD 9.265 or less. The others with a higher income are either transition or industrialized countries (here 21 OECD countries). The grouping of the transition countries is done following the grouping in the OECD country studies (Paris, various years). 31.07.07, C:\ShadEconomyCorruption_July2007.doc 14 and transition countries I use as cause variables the following: share of direct and indirect taxation (including custom duties in % of GDP) as the two tax burden variables; burden of state regulation (Index of regulation, Heritage Foundation, 2006), unemployment quota and GDP per capita as three cause variables for the status of the "official" economy. As indicator values I use the employment quota (in % of the population between 18 and 64), annual rate of GDP, and annual rate of local currency per capita17).For the OECD countries I use as additional cause variables the burden of social security payments, the tax morale, quality of state institutions and an index of the regulation of the labour market, and an additional indicator variable average working time per week. The estimation results for the 96 developing countries in Middle and South America, Africa, Asia and the South West Pacific Islands are shown in table 3.1. All estimated coefficients of the independent cause variables are statistically significant and have the theoretically expected signs. If one first considers the two tax burden variables, one realizes that the share of direct taxation is just statistically significant (90% confidence level) and the size of the estimated coefficient has roughly half the size of the value of the share of indirect taxation and custom duties, which is statistically highly significant. One can interpret this to mean that direct taxation is a less important for the development of the shadow economy in developing countries, compared to indirect taxation and custom duties. If one turns to the burden of state regulation, this variable is highly significant statistically, like the two variables, measuring the official economy, unemployment quota and GDP per capita. As a single independent variable, the burden of state regulation has the quantitatively largest impact on the size of the shadow economy, showing that state regulation is the most important factor for the size of the shadow economy in developing countries. But also the official labour market is quite important: the unemployment quota has the second largest estimated coefficient and influence on the shadow economy in the 96 developing countries in Middle and South America, Africa, Asia and the South West Pacific Islands. If we turn to the indicator variables, we see that the employment quota, as well as the change of local currency per capita, have the expected negative and positive influence and are highly statistically significant, respectively18). 17) Here I have the problem, that in some developing and transition countries the US-$ (or Euro) is also a widely used currency, which is not considered here, because I got no reliable figures of the amount of US-$ (Euro) in these developing and transition countries. 18) The estimation results are in general robust, if other indicator variables are used as residuum; e.g. if the variable currency per capita is used as residuum the share of direct taxation becomes insignificant as well as the variable GPD per capita. 31.07.07, C:\ShadEconomyCorruption_July2007.doc 15 In table 3.2 the DYMIMIC estimation results are presented for the 25 transition countries in Central and East Europe, former Soviet Union countries and 3 communist countries19. Again all estimated coefficients of the cause variables are statistically significant and similar: as in the case of the developing countries. The two tax burden variables have together the quantitatively largest impact on the size of the shadow economy. Contrary to the results found in the 96 developing countries, the cause variable, "share of direct taxation" (including social security payments) has a highly significant statistical influence with the expected positive effect on the shadow economy. Also the independent variable "share of indirect taxation" has now a highly significant statistical influence, but the estimated coefficient is somewhat smaller than compared to the one the share of direct taxation (including social security payments). The variable, "unemployment quota" has also the expected positive influence, is highly statistically significant, and has the second largest estimated coefficient. The indicator variables, "employment quota", and, "the annual rate of currency per capita" have the theoretically expected signs and are statistically highly significant. Finally, in table 3.3 the results for 21 highly developed OECD countries are shown. For these countries the availability of data is somewhat better: Not only have I more data points over time, but also I have three additional cause variables, tax morale (an index), quality of state institutions and now, as a separate variable, the burden of social security payments (in % of official GDP). The additional indicator variable is the average working time (per week)20). The estimated coefficients of all eight cause variables are statistically significant and have the theoretically expected signs. The tax and social security burden variables are quantitatively the most important ones, followed by the tax morale variable which has the single biggest influence; hence the tax payers' attitude towards the state institutions/government is quite important to determine whether one is engaged in shadow economy activities or not. Also the development of the official economy measured in unemployment and GDP per capita has a quantitatively important influence on the shadow economy. Turning to the four indicator variables they all have a statistically significant influence and the estimated coefficients have 19 How useful it is to conclude the three communist countries in this estimation, is an open and debatable question, as these countries have only a somewhat limited market system. Hence they may not fit in this sample, which may be a point of criticism. Hence the calculated shadow economy figures may have a different meansing and should be interpreted with great care. 20) Using this indicator variable one has the problem that, of course, this variable is influenced by state regulation, so that this variable is not really exogenous; hence the estimation may be biased. 31.07.07, C:\ShadEconomyCorruption_July2007.doc 16 the theoretically expected signs. The quantitatively most important independent variables are the employment quota and change of currency per capita21). Summarizing, the econometric results demonstrate that for all three groups of countries the theoretical considerations about the causes of the shadow economy in section 2 can be confirmed: The direct tax (and social security) payment and indirect tax (+ customs tariff) burden variables are the driving forces of the growth of the shadow economy for all three types of countries (developing, transition and highly developed OECD countries), followed by the measure of state (labour market) regulation and, as measures of the official economy, the unemployment quota and GDP per capita. In the developing countries has the largest influence has the burden of state regulation, followed by the unemployment quota and the share of indirect taxation. In the transition countries direct taxation (including social security payments) has the largest influence, followed by the unemployment quota and share of indirect taxation. In the highly developed OECD countries, the social security contributions and the share of direct taxation wield the biggest influence, followed by tax morale and the quality of state institutions. From these results we see that there are some differences, which influence the shadow economy according to these three different country groups. In order to calculate the size and development of the shadow economies of 145 countries, I have to overcome the disadvantage of the DYMIMIC approach, which is that one gets only relatively estimated sizes of the shadow economy and one has to use another approach to get absolute figures. In order to calculate absolute figures of the size of the shadow economies from these DYMIMIC estimation results, I use the already available estimations from the currency demand approach for Australia, Austria, Germany, Hungary, Italy, India, Peru, Russia and the United States (from studies of Chatterjee, Chaudhury and Schneider (2006), Del’Anno and Schneider (2004), Bajada and Schneider (2003, 2005), Alexeev and Pyle (2003), Schneider and Enste (2002) and Lacko (2000)). As I have absolute values of the shadow economy (in % of GDP) for various years for the above mentioned countries, I can use a benchmark procedure to transform the index of the shadow economy from the DYMIMIC estimations into absolute values.22) 21) The variable currency per capita or annual change of currency per capita is heavily influenced by banking innovations; hence this variable is pretty unstable with respect to the length of the estimation period. Similar problems are already mentioned by Giles (1999a) and Giles and Tedds (2002). 22) This procedure is described in great detail in the paper Del’Anno and Schneider (2005). 31.07.07, C:\ShadEconomyCorruption_July2007.doc 17 Table 3.1: DYMIMIC Estimations of the size of the shadow economy of 96 developing countries in Middle and South America, Africa, Asia and the South West Pacific Islands 1999/00, 2001/02, 2002/03, 2003/04 and 2004/05 Cause Variables Share of direct taxation (in % of GDP) Estimated Coefficients λ1 = 0.14(*) (1.70) Share of indirect taxation and customs duties (in % of GDP) λ2 = 0.234** (3.01) Burden of state regulation (Index, Heritage Foundation: score 1 most economic freedom, 5 least economic freedom) λ3 = 0.274** (2.61) Unemployment quota (%) λ4 = 0.317** (4.12) GDP per capita (in US-$) λ5 = -0.143* (-2.21) λ6 = 0.241(*) (1.31) Lagged endogenous variable Indicator Variables Employment quota (in % of population 18-64) Annual rate of GDP Change of local currency per capita Test-statistics λ7 = -0.603* (-2.86) λ8 = -1 (Residuum) λ9 = 0.371** (4.07) RMSE1) = 0.0010(*) (p-value = 0.903) Chi-square2) = 8.50 (p-value = 0.913) TMNCV3) = 0.056 AGFI4) = 0.721 N = 480 D.F.5) = 41 Notes: t-statistics are given in parentheses (*); *; ** means the t-statistics are statistically significant at the 90%, 95%, or 99% confidence level. 1) Steigers Root Mean Square Error of Approximation (RMSEA) for test of close fit; RMSEA < 0.05; the RMSEA-value varies between 0.0 and 1.0. 2) If the structural equation model is asymptotically correct, then the matrix S (sample covariance matrix) will be equal to Σ (θ) (model implied covariance matrix). This test has a statistical validity with a large sample (N ≥ 100) and multinomial distributions; both are given for all three equations in tables 3.1-3.3 using a test of multi normal distributions. 3) Test of Multivariate Normality for Continuous Variables (TMNCV); p-values of skewness and kurtosis. 4) Test of Adjusted Goodness of Fit Index (AGFI), varying between 0 and 1; 1 = perfect fit. 5) The degrees of freedom are determined by 0.5 (p + q) (p + q + 1) – t; with p = number of indicators; q = number of causes; t = the number for free parameters. 31.07.07, C:\ShadEconomyCorruption_July2007.doc 18 Table 3.2: DYMIMIC Estimation of the Shadow Economy of 25 Central and East European and former Soviet Union Countries and 3 Communist Countries, 1999/00, 2001/02, 2002/03, 2003/04 and 2004/05 Cause Variables Share of direct taxation + share of social security payments (in % of GDP) Estimated Coefficients λ1 = 0.387** (3.03) Share of indirect taxation + customs duties (in % of GDP) λ2 = 0.294* (2.62) Burden of state regulation (Index, Heritage Foundation: score 1 most economic freedom, 5 least economic freedom) λ3 = 0.202* (2.56) Unemployment quota (%) λ4 = 0.345** (3.21) GDP per capita (in US-$) λ5 = -0.194** (-2.88) λ6 = 0.214(*) (1.80) Lagged endogenous variable Indicator Variables Employment quota (as % of total population 18-64) Annual rate of GDP Change of local currency per capita Test-statistics λ7 = -0.612** (-3.57) λ8 = -1.00 (Residuum) λ9 = 0.406** (3.20) RMSE1) = 0.0010(*) (p-value = 0.889) Chi-square 2) = 342.66 (p-value = 0.701) TMCV3) = 0.084 AGFI4) = 0.682 N = 140 D.F.5) = 34 Notes: t-statistics are given in parentheses (*); *; ** means the t-statistics are statistically significant at the 90%, 95%, or 99% confidence level. 1) Steigers Root Mean Square Error of Approximation (RMSEA) for test of close fit; RMSEA < 0.05; the RMSEA-value varies between 0.0 and 1.0. 2) If the structural equation model is asymptotically correct, then the matrix S (sample covariance matrix) will be equal to Σ (θ) (model implied covariance matrix). This test has a statistical validity with a large sample (N ≥ 100) and multinomial distributions; both are given for all three equations in tables 3.1.1-3.1.3 using a test of multi normal distributions. 3) Test of Multivariate Normality for Continuous Variables (TMNCV); p-values of skewness and kurtosis. 4) Test of Adjusted Goodness of Fit Index (AGFI), varying between 0 and 1; 1 = perfect fit. 5) The degrees of freedom are determined by 0.5 (p + q) (p + q + 1) – t; with p = number of indicators; q = number of causes; t = the number for free parameters. 31.07.07, C:\ShadEconomyCorruption_July2007.doc 19 Table 3.3: DYMIMIC Estimation of the Shadow Economy of 21 highly developed OECD Countries, 1990/91, 1994/95, 1997/98, 1999/2000, 2001/02, 2002/03, 2003/04 and 2004/05 Cause Variables Share of direct taxation (in % of GDP) Estimated Coefficients λ1 = 0.384** (3.06) Share of indirect taxation (in % of GDP) λ2 = 0.196(*) (1.84) Share of social security contribution (in % of GDP) λ3 = 0.506** (3.86) Burden of state regulation (index of labour market regulation, Heritage Foundation, score 1 least regular, score 5 most regular) λ4 = 0.213(*) (1.96) Quality of state institutions (rule of law, World Bank, score -3 worst and +3 best case) λ5 = -0.307** (-2.61) Tax morale (WUS and EUS, Index, Scale tax cheating always justified =1, never justified =10) λ6 = -0.582** (-3.66) Unemployment quota (%) λ7 = 0.324** (2.61) GDP per capita (in US-$) Indicator Variables Employment quota (in % of population 18-64) λ8 = -0.106** (-3.04) λ9= -0.165(*) (-1.66) Estimated Coefficients λ10= -0.626** (-2.72) Average working time (per week) λ11 = -1.00 (Residuum) Lagged endogenous variable Annual rate of GDP (adjusted for the mean of all 22 OECD countries) Change of local currency per capita Test-statistics λ12 = -0.274** (-3.03) λ13 = 0.312** (3.74) 1) RMSE = 0.0016* (p-value = 0.903) Chi-square2) = 26.43 (p-value = 0.906) TMCV3) = 0.049 AGFI4) = 0.763 N = 168 D.F.5) = 67 Notes: t-statistics are given in parentheses (*); *; ** means the t-statistics are statistically significant at 31.07.07, C:\ShadEconomyCorruption_July2007.doc 20 the 90%, 95%, or 99% confidence level. 1) Steigers Root Mean Square Error of Approximation (RMSEA) for test of close fit; RMSEA < 0.05; the RMSEA-value varies between 0.0 and 1.0. 2) If the structural equation model is asymptotically correct, then the matrix S (sample covariance matrix) will be equal to Σ (θ) (model implied covariance matrix). This test has a statistical validity with a large sample (N ≥ 100) and multinomial distributions; both are given for all three equations in tables 3.1.1-3.1.3 using a test of multi normal distributions. 3) Test of Multivariate Normality for Continuous Variables (TMNCV); p-values of skewness and kurtosis. 4) Test of Adjusted Goodness of Fit Index (AGFI), varying between 0 and 1; 1 = perfect fit. 5) The degrees of freedom are determined by 0.5 (p + q) (p + q + 1) – t; with p = number of indicators; q = number of causes; t = the number for free parameters. 3.2 The Size of the Shadow Economies for 145 Countries for 1999/2000 to 2004/2005 When showing the size of the shadow economies over the five periods of time (1999/2000, 2001/2002, 2002/2003, 2003/2004 and 2004/2005) for the 145 countries which are quite different in location and developing stage, one should be aware that such country comparisons give only a rough picture of the ranking of the size of the shadow economy in these countries and over time, because the DYMIMIC and the currency demand methods have shortcomings; these are discussed in appendix (chapter 5)23). Due to these shortcomings a detailed discussion of the (relative) ranking of the size of the shadow economies is not conducted. 3.2.1 Developing Countries24 The results of the shadow economies for developing countries are divided by continent into Africa, Asia, and Central and South America, and are shown in Tables 3.2.1-3.2.3. The results for thirty-seven African countries are shown in Table 3.2.1. If we first consider the development of the shadow economies in these thirty-seven African countries from 1999/2000 to 2004/2005, we realize that shadow economies in these African nations have increased. On average, the size of these thirty-seven African shadow economies was 41.3% (of official GDP) in 1999-2000, and increased to 42.8% in 2004/2005 but highest average value with 43.2 occurred in the years 2002/03 and 2003/04, since then we have a slight decrease to 42.8% in 2004/05. Turning to the latest results for 2004/2005, Zimbabwe, Nigeria and Tanzania (with 64.6, 59.5 and 58.2% respectively) have by far the largest shadow 23) See also Thomas (1992, 1999), Tanzi (1999), Pedersen (2003) and Ahumada, Alveredo, Cavanese A and P. Cavanese (2004), Janisch and Brümmerhoff (2005), Schneider (2005) and Breusch (2005a, 2005b). 24) For an extensive and excellent literature survey of the research about the shadow economy in developing countries see Gerxhani (2003),who stresses thoroughout her paper that the distinction between developed and developing countries with respect to the shadow economy is of great importance. Due to space reasons this point is not further elabourated here; nor are the former results and literature discussed. Compare Schneider and Enste 31.07.07, C:\ShadEconomyCorruption_July2007.doc 21 economies, and the country in the median position is Mozambique with 43.5%. South Africa has the lowest shadow economy, with 28.2%, followed by Lesotho with 32.3%, and Namibia with 32.4%. The large shadow economy in Africa (and in other developing countries) is only to some extent an issue of tax burdens and regulation, given the simple fact that the limited local economy means that citizens are often unable to earn a living wage in a legitimate manner. Working in the shadow economy is often the only way of achieving a minimal standard of living. Table 3.2.1: The Size of the Shadow Economy in Thirty-Seven African Countries Shadow Economy (in % of official GDP) using the DYMIMIC and Currency Demand Method No. 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 Country Algeria Angola Benin Botswana Burkina Faso Burundi Cameroon Central African Republic Chad Congo, Dem. Rep. Republic of Congo Cote d'Ivoire Egypt, Arabian Republic Ethiopia Ghana Guinea Kenya Lesotho Madagascar Malawi Mali Mauritania Morocco Mozambique Namibia Niger Nigeria Rwanda Senegal Sierra Leone South Africa Tanzania Togo Tunisia 1999/00 34.1 43.2 47.3 33.4 41.4 36.9 32.8 44.3 46.2 48.0 48.2 43.2 35.1 40.3 41.9 39.6 34.3 31.3 39.6 40.3 42.3 36.1 36.4 40.3 31.4 41.9 57.9 40.3 45.1 41.7 28.4 58.3 35.1 38.4 2001/02 35.0 44.1 48.2 33.9 42.6 37.6 33.7 45.4 47.1 48.8 49.1 44.3 36.0 41.4 42.7 40.8 35.1 32.4 40.4 41.2 43.9 37.2 37.1 41.3 32.6 42.6 58.6 41.4 46.8 42.8 29.1 59.4 39.2 39.1 2002/03 35.6 45.2 49.1 34.6 43.3 38.7 34.9 46.1 48.0 49.7 50.1 45.2 36.9 42.1 43.6 41.3 36.0 33.3 41.6 42.1 44.7 38.0 37.9 42.4 33.4 43.8 59.4 42.2 47.5 43.9 29.5 60.2 40.4 39.9 2003/04 34.8 45.3 49.3 34.2 43.8 39.4 34.4 46.3 48.4 50.4 50.5 45.4 36.3 42.7 43.8 41.7 35.4 32.8 41.9 42.7 44.0 37.4 37.3 42.9 33.0 44.1 59.6 42.4 47.8 44.1 29.0 59.1 40.6 39.4 2004/05 33.9 45.0 49.8 33.8 43.1 39.7 33.6 46.9 47.8 50.8 51.1 44.7 35.4 42.0 43.2 41.0 34.8 32.3 41.2 41.9 43.2 36.8 36.7 43.5 32.4 44.2 59.5 41.6 48.2 44.3 28.2 58.2 39.4 38.3 (2000) 31.07.07, C:\ShadEconomyCorruption_July2007.doc 22 35 Uganda 36 Zambia 37 Zimbabwe Unweighted Average 43.1 48.9 59.4 41.3 44.6 49.7 61.0 42.3 45.4 50.8 63.2 43.2 45.8 50.2 63.9 43.2 44.9 49.3 64.6 42.8 Source: Own calculations. In Table 3.2.2, the results for twenty-eight Asian countries are shown. It is somewhat difficult to treat all Asian countries equally, because some, such as Israel, Singapore, and Hong Kong, are highly developed, while others, such as Thailand and Nepal, are still developing. The average shadow economy in the region increased from 28.5% in 1999/2000, to 29.8% of official GDP in 2004/2005; however in 2002/03 the shadow economies of most Asian countries reached a peak value with 30.4% (average value over the 28 countries) which decreased to 29.8% (average) in 2004/05. Looking at individual countries25) for the year 2004/2005, with 53.6% Thailand has by far the largest shadow economy, followed by Cambodia with 52.2%, and Sri Lanka with 48.8% of official GDP. The median country is the Republic of South Korea with 27.6% of official GDP, surrounded by Yemen with 27.3% and United Arab Emirates with 26.5%. Singapore, Hong Kong and Saudi Arabia have the lowest shadow economies with 12.1%, 15.6%, and 18.4% of official GDP, respectively. It is somewhat astonishing that the average size of the Asian shadow economies is considerably smaller than the shadow economies of African and Latin American states––this is partly due to the fact that there are a greater number of developed countries, which have smaller shadow economies located in Asia. It should be noted, however, that the average increase of shadow economies in the region is slightly more rapid than in Africa. This is not surprising, given that the size of the average African shadow economy is already more than eleven percentage points higher than its Asian counterpart. There is simply more room for growth in Asia. In Table 3.2.3, the sizes of shadow for twenty-one Central and South American countries are shown. Averaging the figures over all twenty-one Central and South American countries, the shadow economy increased from 41.1% in the year 1999/2000 to 42.2% of official GDP in 2004/2005; however, in 2002/03 the shadow economies of most Central and South American countries reached a peak value with 43.4% (average of over the 21 countries), which decreased then to 42.2% (average) in 2004/05. If I turn to the size of the shadow economy for single countries for 2004/2005, Bolivia has the largest shadow economy with 67.2%, followed by Panama with 62.2% and Peru with 58.2% of official GDP. The median country is 25) The case of India has been extensively investigated by Chatterjee, Chaudhury and Schneider (2006). 31.07.07, C:\ShadEconomyCorruption_July2007.doc 23 Brazil with 41.8% and at the lower end is Chile with 19.4%, Costa Rica with 26.3%, and Argentina with 27.2% of official GDP. The sizes of the shadow economies of African and Central and South American countries are generally similar. This is partly due to the factors mentioned earlier; for the majority of citizens in many of these countries, the only way to ensure a decent standard of living is to turn to the black market. As income inequality is much more pronounced in most Central and South American countries, compared to Africa, the rate of increase in shadow economy activity in Central and South America is higher. Table 3.2.2: The Size of the Shadow Economy in Twenty-Eight Asian Countries Shadow Economy (in % of official GDP) using the DYMIMIC and Currency Demand Method Country 1 Bangladesh 2 Bhutan 3 Cambodia 4 Hong Kong, China 5 India 6 Indonesia 7 Iran, Islamic Republic 8 Israel 9 Jordan 10 Korea, Republic 11 Kuwait 12 Lebanon 13 Malaysia 14 Mongolia 15 Nepal 16 Oman 17 Pakistan 18 Papua New Guinea 19 Philippines 20 Saudi Arabia 21 Singapore 22 Sri Lanka 23 Syrian Arab Republic 24 Taiwan, China 25 Thailand 26 Turkey 27 United Arab Emirates 28 Yemen, Rep. Unweighted Average No. 1999/00 35.6 29.4 50.1 16.6 23.1 19.4 18.9 21.9 19.4 27.5 20.1 34.1 31.1 18.4 38.4 18.9 36.8 36.1 43.4 18.4 13.1 44.6 19.3 25.4 52.6 32.1 26.4 27.4 28.5 2001/02 36.5 30.5 51.3 17.1 24.2 21.8 19.4 22.8 20.5 28.1 20.7 35.6 31.6 19.6 39.7 19.4 37.9 37.3 44.5 19.1 13.4 45.9 20.4 26.6 53.4 33.2 27.1 28.4 29.5 2002/03 37.7 31.7 52.4 17.2 25.6 22.9 19.9 23.9 21.6 28.8 21.6 36.2 32.2 20.4 40.8 19.8 38.7 38.6 45.6 19.7 13.7 47.2 21.6 27.7 54.1 34.3 27.8 29.1 30.4 2003/04 38.3 32.7 52.9 16.4 25.9 23.6 20.2 23.2 21.2 28.2 21.2 36.5 32.0 20.6 40.2 19.2 39.2 38.0 45.1 19.3 13.0 48.3 21.7 27.0 54.3 33.9 27.2 28.2 30.3 2004/05 38.0 33.1 52.2 15.6 25.1 24.0 19.7 22.6 20.4 27.6 20.7 37.1 31.4 21.2 39.3 18.6 39.5 37.3 44.3 18.4 12.1 48.8 21.2 26.3 53.6 33.2 26.5 27.3 29.8 Source: Own calculations. 31.07.07, C:\ShadEconomyCorruption_July2007.doc 24 Table 3.2.3: The Size of the Shadow Economy in Twenty-One Central and South American Countries Shadow Economy (in % of official GDP) using the DYMIMIC and Currency Demand Method Country 1 Argentina 2 Bolivia 3 Brazil 4 Chile 5 Colombia 6 Costa Rica 7 Dominican Republic 8 Ecuador 9 El Salvador 10 Guatemala 11 Haiti 12 Honduras 13 Jamaica 14 Mexico 15 Nicaragua 16 Panama 17 Paraguay 18 Peru 19 Puerto Rico 20 Uruguay 21 Venezuela, RB Unweighted Average No. 1999/00 25.4 67.1 39.8 19.8 39.1 26.2 32.1 34.4 46.3 51.5 55.4 49.6 36.4 30.1 45.2 64.1 27.4 59.9 28.4 51.1 33.6 41.1 2001/02 27.1 68.1 40.9 20.3 41.3 27.0 33.4 35.1 47.1 51.9 57.1 50.8 37.8 31.8 46.9 65.1 29.2 60.3 29.4 51.4 35.1 42.2 2002/03 28.9 68.3 42.3 20.9 43.4 27.8 34.1 36.7 48.3 52.4 58.6 51.6 38.9 33.2 48.2 65.3 31.4 60.9 30.7 51.9 36.7 43.4 2003/04 28.6 68.0 42.6 20.3 43.0 27.1 34.4 36.1 48.1 51.1 59.3 50.8 39.2 32.6 48.8 64.1 32.4 59.1 29.6 50.8 36.1 43.0 2004/05 27.2 67.2 41.8 19.4 42.7 26.3 34.8 35.2 47.2 50.3 59.6 49.3 38.4 31.7 48.1 62.2 33.1 58.2 28.2 49.2 35.4 42.2 Source: Own calculations. 3.2.2 Transition Countries The measurement of the size and development of the shadow economies in the transition countries has been undertaken since the late 1980s starting with the work of Kaufmann and Kaliberda (1996), Johnson et al. (1997) and Lacko (2000). They all use the physical input (electricity) method (see Appendix 7.1.2.5) and come up with quite large figures. In the work of Alexeev and Pyle (2003) and Belev (2003) the above mentioned studies are critically evaluated arguing that the estimated sizes of the unofficial economies are to a large extent a historical phenomenon and partly determined by institutional factors. In table 3.2.4 the size and development of the shadow economy of 25 East and Central European and former Soviet Union countries are presented. Turning again first to the development of the size of the shadow economy over time, the average size of the shadow economy of these 25 East and Central European countries was 38.1% of official GDP in 1999/2000 and increased to 38.8% in 2004/2005; however, the average size of the shadow economies of these 25 East and Central 31.07.07, C:\ShadEconomyCorruption_July2007.doc 25 European and Former Soviet Union countries reached a peak value of 40.1% in 2002/03 and since then declined to 38.8% in 2004/05. The highest shadow economies are in Georgia, Azerbaijan and the Ukraine with 66.4%, 59.4% and 55.3%. The median country is Bulgaria, surrounded by Serbia and Montenegro with 37.3% and Romania with 35.4%. At the lower end are the Czech Republic with 18.3%, the Slovak Republic with 18.2% and Hungary with 24.3% of official GDP. Table 3.2.4: The Size of the Shadow Economy in 25 East and Central European and Former Soviet Union Countries Shadow Economy (in % of official GDP) using the DYMIMIC and Currency Demand Method Country 1 Albania 2 Armenia 3 Azerbaijan 4 Belarus 5 Bosnia and Herzegovina 6 Bulgaria 7 Croatia 8 Czech Republic 9 Estonia 10 Georgia 11 Hungary 12 Kazakhstan 13 Kyrgyz Republic 14 Latvia 15 Lithuania 16 Macedonia, FYR 17 Moldova 18 Poland 19 Romania 20 Russian Federation 21 Serbia and Montenegro 22 Slovak Republic 23 Slovenia 24 Ukraine 25 Uzbekistan Unweighted Average No. 1999/00 33.4 46.3 60.6 48.1 34.1 36.9 33.4 19.1 38.4 67.3 25.1 43.2 39.8 39.9 30.3 34.1 45.1 27.6 34.4 46.1 36.4 18.9 27.1 52.2 34.1 38.1 2001/02 34.6 47.8 61.1 49.3 35.4 37.1 34.2 19.6 39.2 67.6 25.7 44.1 40.3 40.7 31.4 35.1 47.3 28.2 36.1 47.5 37.3 19.3 28.3 53.6 35.7 39.1 2002/03 35.3 49.1 61.3 50.4 36.7 38.3 35.4 20.1 40.1 68.0 26.2 45.2 41.2 41.3 32.6 36.3 49.4 28.9 37.4 48.7 39.1 20.2 29.4 54.7 37.2 40.1 2003/04 35.0 48.4 60.8 50.5 36.2 37.4 34.7 19.2 39.1 67.3 25.3 45.4 41.4 40.4 31.3 36.8 49.5 28.2 36.2 48.2 38.2 19.1 28.2 54.9 36.3 39.5 2004/05 34.3 47.6 59.4 50.8 35.3 36.5 34.1 18.3 38.2 66.4 24.3 44.6 40.6 39.4 30.2 36.9 49.1 27.3 35.4 47.3 37.3 18.2 27.3 55.3 35.4 38.8 Source: Own calculations. 3.2.3 Highly developed OECD-Countries The size and development of the shadow economies of 21 highly developed OECD countries are shown in table 3.2.5. 31.07.07, C:\ShadEconomyCorruption_July2007.doc 26 Table 3.2.5: The Size of the Shadow Economy in 21 OECD Countries Shadow Economy (in % of official GDP) using the DYMIMIC and Currency Demand Method Country 1 Australia 2 Austria 3 Belgium 4 Canada 5 Denmark 6 Finland 7 France 8 Germany 9 Greece 10 Ireland 11 Italy 12 Japan 13 Netherlands 14 New Zealand 15 Norway 16 Portugal 17 Spain 18 Sweden 19 Switzerland 20 United Kingdom 21 United States Unweighted Average 1999/00 14.3 9.8 22.2 16.0 18.0 18.1 15.2 16.0 28.7 15.9 27.1 11.2 13.1 12.8 19.1 22.7 22.7 19.2 8.6 12.7 8.7 16.8 2001/02 14.1 10.6 22.0 15.8 17.9 18.0 15.0 16.3 28.5 15.7 27.0 11.1 13.0 12.6 19.0 22.5 22.5 19.1 9.4 12.5 8.7 16.7 2002/03 13.5 10.9 21.0 15.2 17.3 17.4 14.5 16.8 28.2 15.3 25.7 10.8 12.6 12.3 18.4 21.9 22.0 18.3 9.4 12.2 8.4 16.3 2003/04 13.1 10.1 20.4 14.8 16.7 16.4 13.8 16.1 27.4 14.8 24.8 9.4 12.0 11.6 17.6 21.1 21.2 17.2 9.0 11.7 8.2 15.6 2004/05 12.8 9.3 19.6 14.1 16.1 15.8 13.2 15.3 26.3 14.1 23.2 8.8 11.1 10.9 16.8 20.4 20.5 16.3 8.5 10.3 7.9 14.8 Source: Own calculations. If I consider again the development of the size of the shadow economies of these 21 OECD countries, I realize for the first time that the size of the shadow economy of these countries has decreased over the period 1999/2000 to 2004/2005. The average size of the shadow economy in 1999/2000 of these countries was 16.8% of official GDP; it decreased to 14.8% in 2004/2005. If I consider single countries, Greece, Italy and Spain have by far the largest shadow economy in 2004/2005 with 26.3%, 23.2% and 20.5% of official GDP. The median country is Ireland with 14.1% of official GDP surrounded by Germany with 15.3%26) and Canada with 14.1%. At the lower end are the United States, Switzerland and Japan with a shadow economy of 7.9%, 8.5% and 8.8% of official GDP. 3.2.4 South West Pacific Islands The size and development of the shadow economies of 10 South West Pacific islands are presented in table 3.2.6. 26) Pickhardt and Sarda-Pous (2006) reach very similar values of the shadow economy for Germany using a 31.07.07, C:\ShadEconomyCorruption_July2007.doc 27 Table 3.2.6.: The Size of the Shadow Economy in 10 South West Pacific Islands Shadow Economy (in % of official GDP) using the DYMIMIC and Currency Demand Method Country 1 Fiji 2 Kiribati 3 Maldives 4 Marshall Islands 5 Micronesia, Fed. Sts. 6 Palau 7 Samoa 8 Solomon Islands 9 Tonga 10 Vanuatu Unweighted Average 1999/00 33.6 34.1 30.3 28.1 31.3 28.4 31.4 33.4 35.1 30.9 31.7 2001/02 34.3 35.0 31.4 29.0 32.1 29.2 32.6 34.5 36.3 31.7 32.6 2002/03 35.1 35.3 32.0 29.6 33.2 30.0 33.5 35.3 37.4 32.5 33.4 2003/04 34.6 34.8 31.6 28.7 32.6 29.2 33.1 34.6 36.8 32.0 32.8 2004/05 33.8 34.0 30.9 27.9 31.9 28.4 32.8 34.0 35.8 31.4 32.1 Source: Own calculations. If I again consider the development over time, the average size of the shadow economy of these 10 South West Pacific islands countries increased from 31.7% in the year 1999/2000 to 32.1% in the year 2004/2005; however, the average value of these 10 West Pacific Islands reached a peak value of 33.4% in 2002/03 and since then declined to 32.1% in 2004/05. Considering the largest shadow economy is in Tonga, with 35.8%, followed by the Solomon Islands with 34.0% and Kiribati with 34.0%. In the middle field is Micronesia and Samoa with a shadow economy of 31.9% and 32.8% of official GDP. The lowest shadow economy have the Marshall Islands and Palau with a shadow economy of 27.9% and 28.4%. 3.2.5 Communist Countries In this last section the size and development of the shadow economies of three communist countries (China, Laos and Vietnam) are presented. The results are shown in table 3.2.7. Table 3.2.7: The Size of the Shadow Economy in 3 Communist Countries Shadow Economy (in % of official GDP) using the DYMIMIC and Currency Demand Method Country 1 China 2 Lao PDR 3 Vietnam Unweighted Average No. 1999/00 13.1 30.6 15.6 19.8 2001/02 14.4 31.9 16.9 21.1 2002/03 15.6 33.4 17.9 22.3 2003/04 16.1 33.9 16.9 22.3 2004/05 16.6 33.2 16.1 22.0 Source: Own calculations. combination of a MIMIC and Currency Demand Method. 31.07.07, C:\ShadEconomyCorruption_July2007.doc 28 The average size of the shadow economy in the above mentioned countries in 1999/2000 was 19.8%, and by 2004/2005 had increased to 22.0%. Laos has the largest shadow economy with 33.2% and Vietnam the lowest with 16.1%. It should be clear that the shadow economy in these countries, and especially in China (16.6%), which is partly a market economy and yet still a planned socialist economy, is difficult to interpret. It should be more seen as a parallel economy, where especially farmers and small firms in rural regions produce additional products to earn some (extra) money. It is an open question whether the findings of these shadow economies can be compared to others. That is one reason why they are shown in this paper in an extra section and should be interpreted with caution with respect to their size and the label "shadow" or "grey" economy. 4 Corruption and the Shadow Economy: Substitutes or Compliments?27) Quite often shadow economy and corruption28) are seen as "twins", who need each other or fight against each other. This means for a social scientist that, theoretically, corruption and the shadow economy can be either complements or substitutes. Choi and Thum (2004) present a model where the option of entrepreneurs to go underground constrains a corrupt official’s ability to ask for bribes. Dreher, Kotsogiannis and McCorriston (2005a/b) extend the model to the explicit specification of institutional quality. The model shows that corruption and shadow economy are substitutes in the sense that the existence of the shadow economy reduces the propensity of officials to demand graft. Johnson et al. (1998), on the contrary, model corruption and the shadow economy as complements. In their full-employment model, labour can be either employed in the official sector or in the underground economy. Consequently, an increase in the shadow economy always decreases the size of the official market. In their model, corruption increases the shadow economy, as corruption can be viewed as one particular form of taxation and regulation (driving entrepreneurs underground). Hindriks et al. (1999) also show that the shadow economy is a complement to corruption. This is because, in this case, the tax payer 27) This section is taken from Dreher and Schneider (2006), pages 4, 5 and 14 as well as table 4.1. According to Dreher and Schneider (2006), corruption is commonly defined as the misuse of public power for private benefit. 28) 31.07.07, C:\ShadEconomyCorruption_July2007.doc 29 colludes with the inspector so the inspector under-reports the tax liability of the tax payer in exchange for a bribe29). Theoretically, the relationship between corruption and the shadow economy is thus unsettled. There is, however, reason to believe that the relationship might differ among high and low income countries. In high income countries, the official sector provides public goods like the rule of law, enforcement of contracts, and protection by an efficient police. Usually, only craftsmen or very small firms have (or take) the option of going underground. In this case, the shadow economy is hidden from tax inspectors and other officials. In other words, there are no bribes necessary or possible to buy the way out of the official sector. In high income countries – typically showing comparably small levels of corruption – individuals confronted with a corrupt official always have the choice to bring the official to court. Moreover, in high income countries corruption quite often takes place, for example, to bribe officials to get a (huge) contract from the public sector (e.g. in the construction sector). This contract is then handled in the official economy and not in the shadow economy. Hence, corruption in high income countries can be a means to achieve certain benefits which make work in the official economy easier, e.g., winning a contract from a public authority, getting a licence (e.g. for operating taxes or providing other services or getting the permission to convert land into "construction ready" land, etc.). In high income countries people thus bribe in order to be able to engage in more official economic activities. As Schneider and Enste (2000) point out, at least two thirds of the income earned in the shadow economy is immediately spent in the official sector. The shadow economy and the official sector might thus be complements. The corresponding increase in government revenue and strengthened institutional quality is likely to decrease corruption. The prediction of a negative (substitutive) relation between corruption and the shadow economy is in line with the models of Choi and Thum (2004) and Dreher, Kotsogiannis and McCorriston (2005a).30) In low income countries, on the contrary, we expect different mechanisms to prevail. Instead of working partly in the official sector and offering additional services underground as in high-income countries, enterprises completely engage in underground activity. Examples for enterprises operating completely underground are restaurants, bars, or haircutters – and even big production companies. One reason for this is that public goods provided by the official sector are, in many developing countries, less efficient compared to high income countries. 29) 30) See Dreher and Siemers (2005) for a formalization of this argument. Consequently, Dreher, Kotsogiannis and McCorriston (2005a) test their model employing data for OECD 31.07.07, C:\ShadEconomyCorruption_July2007.doc 30 Big companies, however, are comparably easy to detect and – in order to escape taxation and punishment – they have to bribe officials, thereby increasing corruption. Corruption often takes place in order to pay for activities in the shadow economy, so that the shadow economy entrepreneur can be sure not to be detected by public authorities. Here, shadow economy and corruption are likely to reinforce each other, as corruption is needed to expand shadow economy activities and – at the same time – underground activities require bribes and corruption. To get some additional income from the shadow economy entrepreneur, it is natural for public officials to ask for bribes and thus benefit from the shadow market. In low income countries, we therefore expect a positive (complementary) relationship between corruption and the shadow economy. This corresponds to the predictions of the models of Hindriks et al. (1999) and Johnson et al. (1997). In summary, following Dreher and Schneider (2006), I expect: Hypothesis 1: In low income countries, shadow economy activities and corruption are complements. Hypothesis 2: In high income countries, shadow economy activities and corruption are substitutes. These two hypotheses are tested for a cross-section of 120 countries and a panel of 70 countries for the period 1994 to 2002.31) Table 4.1 summarizes the empirical results of Dreher and Schneider (2006). Overall, they show that an increase in perceived corruption over time also increases the shadow economy. This confirms the models of Johnson et al. (1998) and Hindriks et al. (1999). Across countries, however, greater perceived corruption does not lead to a greater shadow economy. To some extent this also supports the results of Méon and Sekkat (2004) showing the within-country variation to be important in their analysis of corruption on foreign direct investment and exports. Regarding the impact of the shadow economy on perceived corruption, these results for the overall sample are similar to those for the other way round. In the cross-country regressions, all coefficients are completely insignificant. An increase in the shadow economy over time increases corruption according to the fixed and random effects estimator, but not when the endogeneity of the shadow is controlled. Turning to the sub-samples, the results show that higher perceived corruption significantly reduces the shadow economy in high income countries only. 31) For the description of the data, the estimation techniques used, and the various specification see Dreher and Schneider (2006, chapters 3 and 4). 31.07.07, C:\ShadEconomyCorruption_July2007.doc 31 countries, confirming the models of Choi and Thum (2004) and Dreher, Kotsogiannis and McCorriston (2005a). In low income countries, on the contrary, corruption tends to increase with a higher shadow economy, again confirming the models of Johnson et al. (1998) and Hindriks et al. (1999). This is true for the impact of perceived corruption in the within-groups specification and actual corruption in all specifications. Table 4.1: Empirical Results of the Relationship between the Shadow Economy and Corruption Dependent Variable: Shadow Economy Corruption Independent Variable: Corruption Shadow Economy Estimation technique All Low High All Low High ICRG index of corruption OLS 1.88 3.57 -0,84 0.00 0.01 -0.07 (1.20) (1.34) (0.97) (0.41) (1.14) (3.57***) Robust regression 1.32 0.00 (0.82) (0.43) IV, set 1 3.72 3.12 5.41 -0.03 -0.01 -0.09 (1.17) (0.86) (1.40) (1.28) (0.42) (1.57) IV, set 2 -4.04 5.14 -1.85 -0.02 -0.02 -0.11 (1.33) (0.78) (1.91*) (0.66) (0.46) (1.45) Panel, fixed effects 1.34 1.36 0.69 0.09 0.10 0.09 (2.63**) (1.42) (1.98**) (2.88***) (2.77***) (0.76) Panel, random effects 1.59 0.02 (4.81***) (2.64***) Panel IV 3.46 0.01 (0.12) (3.48***) TI index of corruption OLS -0.06 (2.35**) World Bank Index of corruption OLS -0.01 (2.76**) DKM index of corruption OLS 0.04 0.06 -0.10 (1.77*) (2.49**) (1.50) Robust regression 0.04 (1.69*) IV, set 1 0.14 0.10 -0.32 (2.59**) (2.65**) (1.22) IV, set 2 0.12 0.12 0.04 (2.45**) (2.50**) (0.19) Notes: Higher values represent more corruption; corruption indices used: ICRG International Country Risk Guide; TI=Transparency International; World Bank Index of Corruption; and DKM-Index of Dreher, Kotsogiannis and McCorriston. 31.07.07, C:\ShadEconomyCorruption_July2007.doc 32 Instruments for the shadow economy are: (1) Credit Market Regulations (Fraser), Minimum Wage Regulation (Fraser), Government Effectiveness (World Bank); (2) Starting a Business (Duration), Starting a Business (Costs), Flexibility to Hire, Flexibility to Fire. Instruments for corruption are: (1) Fiscal Burden (Heritage), Regulation of Prices (Fraser), Rule of Law (World Bank), Democracy; (2) Ethnic Fractionalization, Religious Fractionalization, Latitude, French Legacy, Socialist Legacy, German Legacy, Scandinavian Legacy. * denotes significant at 10% level; ** significant at 5% level; *** significant at 1% level Source: Dreher and Schneider (2006, table 12). 5 Summary and Conclusions There have been many obstacles to overcome to measure the size of the shadow economy, to analyze its consequences on the official economy and the interaction between corruption and the shadow economy, but as this paper shows some progress has been made. I provided estimates of the size of the shadow economies for 145 countries for five periods of time (1999/2000, 2001/2002, 2002/2003, 2003/04 and 2004/05) using the DYMIMIC and for the econometric estimation the currency demand approach for calibrating the values into absolute ones. Coming back to the headline of this paper, some new knowledge/insights are gained with respect to the size and development of the shadow economy of 145 countries,32) and to the relationship between the shadow economy and corruption leading to four conclusions: The first conclusion from these results is that for all countries investigated the shadow economy has reached a remarkably large size; the summarized results are shown in table 5.1. This table clearly shows that the average size of the shadow economies of all seven groups of countries (mostly developing countries in Africa, Central and South America, Asia, Transition countries, highly developed OECD countries, South Pacific Islands and Communist Countries) reached a peak value of 35.2% of official GDP in 2002/03 and sine then declined to 34.5% in 2004/05. Hence the first conclusion is that in later years the shadow economies of most of these countries is modestly shrinking! 32) In the appendix some critical discussion of these two methods is given; they have well known weaknesses (compare also Pedersen, 2003). 31.07.07, C:\ShadEconomyCorruption_July2007.doc 33 Table 5.1: Average Size of the Shadow Economy for Developing, Transition and OECDCountries in % of official GDP Average Size of the Shadow Economy – Value added in % of official GDP using DYMIMIC for estimation and Currency Countries/Year Demand method for calibration (Number of Countries) Mostly developing countries: Africa 16.8 (21) 2000/2001 42.3 (37) 42.1 (21) 29.5 (28) 39.1 (25) 16.7 (21) 2002/2003 43.2 (37) 43.4 (21) 30.4 (28) 40.1 (25) 16.3 (21) 2003/2004 43.2 (37) 43.0 (21) 30.3 (28) 39.5 (25) 15.6 (21) 2004/2005 42.8 (37) 42.2 (21) 29.8 (28) 38.8 (25) 14.8 (21) South Pacific Islands 31.7 (10) 32.6 (10) 33.4 (10) 32.8 (10) 32.1 (10) Communist Countries 19.8 (3) 21.1 (3) 22.3 (3) 22.3 (3) 22.0 (3) Unweighted Average over 145 Countries Source: Own calculations. 33.6 34.5 35.2 34.9 34.3 Central and South America Asia Transition countries Highly developed Countries OECD 1999/2000 41.3 (37) 41.1 (21) 28.5 (28) 38.1 (25) The second conclusion is that shadow economies are a complex phenomenon present to an important extent in all type of economies (developing, transition and highly developed). People engage in shadow economic activity for a variety of reasons, among the most important of which we can count are government actions, most notably, taxation and regulation. Considering a public choice perspective a third conclusion for highly developed countries is that a government may not have a great interest to reduce the shadow economy due to the fact that: (i) tax losses my be moderate, as at least 2/3 of the the income earned in the shadow economy is immediately spent in the official economy, (ii) income earned in the shadow economy increases the standard of living of at least 1/3 of the working population, 31.07.07, C:\ShadEconomyCorruption_July2007.doc 34 (iii) between 40 and 50% of the shadow economy activities have a complementary character, which means that additional value added his created, which increases the official (overall) GDP, and (iv) people who work in the shadow economy have less time for other things like going to demonstrations, etc. Considering these three conclusions, it is obvious that one of the big challenges for every government is to undertake efficient incentive orientated policy measures in order to make work less attractive in the shadow economy and hence to make the work in the official economy more attractive. In a number of OECD countries this policy direction has been successfully implemented and this has led to a reduction of the shadow economy. The fourth conclusion is that the shadow economy reduces corruption in high income countries (substitution effect) and increases corruption in low income countries (complementary effect). 6 Appendix 1: Methods to Estimate the Size of the Shadow Economy: The DYMIMIC and Currency Demand Approach As has already been mentioned in chapters 2 and 3, estimating the size and development of a shadow economy is a difficult and challenging task. In this appendix, I give a short but comprehensive overview of the currency demand and the DYMIMIC-approach; each is briefly discussed as well as critically evaluated.33) 6.1 6.1.1 Direct Approaches Survey Method These are micro approaches that employ both well designed surveys and samples based on voluntary replies, or tax auditing and other compliance methods. Sample surveys designed to estimate the shadow economy are widely used in a number of countries34). The main disadvantage of this method is that it presents the flaws of all surveys. For example, the average precision and results depend greatly on the respondent’s willingness to cooperate, it is 33) A discussion and critical evaluation of all used approaches is given in Schneider (2005, 2007). The direct method of voluntary sample surveys has been extensively used for Norway by Isachsen, Klovland and Strom (1982), and Isachsen and Strom (1985). For Denmark this method is used by Mogensen et. al. (1995) in which they report "estimates" of the shadow economy of 2.7 percent of GDP for 1989, of 4.2 percent of GDP for 1991, of 3.0 percent of GDP for 1993 and of 3.1 percent of GDP for 1994. In Pedersen (2003) estimates of the Danish shadow economy contain the years 1995 with 3.1% up to 2001 with 3.8%. This method is also used 34) 31.07.07, C:\ShadEconomyCorruption_July2007.doc 35 difficult to assess the amount of undeclared work from a direct questionnaire, most interviewers hesitate to confess fraudulent behaviour, and responses are of uncertain reliability, which makes it difficult to calculate a real estimate (in monetary terms) of the extent of undeclared work. The main advantage of this method lies in the detailed information about the structure of the shadow economy, but the results from these kinds of surveys are very sensitive to the way the questionnaire is formulated35). In order to demonstrate the difficulties of calculating a macro estimation for a whole country from survey results of shadow economy activities (from single individuals) the following example is used: in Austria the author undertook a representative questioning of the Austrian population in order to estimate the size of the shadow economy in the construction and craftsman sector (including repairing) in November/December 2002 considering three groups. 1. A representative sample of the Austrian population between 16 and 65 years old, 2. 55 self-declared shadow economy workers in the construction and craftsmen sector, and 3. 320 managers (owners) of construction and craftsmen firms. The following results were gained: (1) Among the Austrian population (potential labour force) are 918,000 Austrians who supplied shadow economy activities in the construction and craftsmen sector. Their average hourly earning in the shadow economy varies between €15.30 and €15.60, and the average yearly income from shadow economy activities varies between €1,117.00 and €1.142.00. This means that 73 hours per year were worked in the shadow economy. (2) Among the 55 self-declared shadow economy workers I got a wage rate of €11.50 per hour and annual earnings in the shadow economy of €2,480.00 using the fact that these groups worked 245 hours per year in the shadow economy. (3) Managers (owners) of construction and craftsmanship firms report a wage rate for shadow economy workers of €17 per hour and average earnings per year of €4,590.00, assuming that 270 hours per year were used for shadow economy activities by their employees/workers. The questioned managers also state: 21% of the managers questioned also stated that more than 50% of their employees work in the shadow economy, 41% indicated a figure of less than 50% and 34% reported that no-one in the firm works in the shadow economy. To summarize, 62% of the managers acknowledge that a large percentage of their employees work in the by Williams (2004a). 35) The advantages and disadvantages of this method are extensively dealt by Pedersen (2003), Mogensen et. al (1995) and Feld and Larsen (2005) in their excellent and very carefully done investigations. Compare also the careful and detailed studies by Kazemier (2005a,b), who extensitively discusses the pros .and cons of this method. 31.07.07, C:\ShadEconomyCorruption_July2007.doc 36 shadow economy. Further results are that 7% of the managers think that their employees work between 0 and 2 hours per week in the shadow economy; 29% assume that they work between 6 and 10 hours, 28% between 3 and 5 hours and 14% think that their employees work more then 10 hours per week in the shadow economy; 22% of all managers have no knowledge of this fact. In principle 39% of managers are not in favour (do not support) moonlighting by their workers and 61% are in favour (do support) - an amazingly high percentage! Finally in table 6.1 the aggregate values of the size of the shadow economy in the construction and craftsmen sector in the year 2002 are presented, based on questionnaire findings. Table 6.1 clearly demonstrates that the size of the shadow economy in the construction and craftsmen sector varies considerably from a total value of €2.6 billion up to €4.2 billion. These differences originate from different hourly wages rates, ranging from €11.50 to €17 and from the different amount of hours worked per year in the shadow economy ranging from 245 to 270. Hence the survey method "covers" between 31.2% and 50.9 % of the value obtained by a macro approach (mimic method). These results still leave a considerable leeway, but the rather large differences may be explained by the following facts: 1. Table 5.1 contains earnings and not the value added of the shadow economy. 2. Shadow economy demanders are overwhelmingly households, the whole area of the shadow economy activities between firms (which are especially a problem in the construction and craftsmen sectors) are not considered. 3. All foreign shadow economy activities achieved by foreigners (illegal immigrants) are not considered. 4. The amount earned in the shadow economy (hourly wage rate and hours worked per year), vary considerably. 31.07.07, C:\ShadEconomyCorruption_July2007.doc 37 Table 6.1: Size of the supplied shadow economy in the construction and craftsmen sector, Austria 2002, based on the questionnaire findings Variable/Indicator Worked hours and earning in the shadow economy results from results from managers of results from managers of results from construction declared construction declared and moonlighters and craftsmen moonlighters craftsmen (1) firms (3) firms (2) (4) ∅ hourly shadow economy wage rate €11.5 €17 €11.5 €17 ∅ average yearly €2,814 €4,165 €3,105 €4,590 earning ∅ amount of hours worked in the shadow 245 245 270 270 economy per year per worker ∅ aggregated yearly amount of hours 225.1 million 225.1 million 248.1 million 248.1 million worked in the shadow economy 1) Total earnings of the €2,588.65 €3,826.7 €2,853.15 €4,217.7 shadow economy in million million million million the year 2002 Total shadow economy earnings in % of the value added of the shadow economy in the 31.2 46.1 34.4 50.9 construction and craftsmanship sector (including repairing); absolute value €8,284 billion in 2002 1) Basis of the calculation: 918,864 shadow economy workers in the construction and craftsmen sector. Source: Own calculations. 6.1.2 Tax Auditing Method Estimates of the shadow economy can also be based on the discrepancy between income declared for tax purposes and that measured by selective checks. Fiscal auditing programmes have been particularly effective in this regard. Since these programs are designed to measure the amount of undeclared taxable income, they may also be used to calculate the shadow 31.07.07, C:\ShadEconomyCorruption_July2007.doc 38 economy.36) However, a number of difficulties beset this approach. First, using tax compliance data is equivalent to using a (possibly biased) sample of the population. In general, the selection of tax payers for tax audit is not random but based on properties of submitted (tax) returns that indicate a certain likelihood of (tax) fraud. Consequently, such a sample is not a random one of the whole population, and estimates of the shadow based upon a biased sample may not be accurate. Second estimates based on tax audits reflect only that portion of shadow economy income that the authorities succeed in discovering, and this is likely to be only a fraction of hidden income. A further disadvantage of these two direct methods (surveys and tax auditing) is that they lead only to point estimates. Moreover, it is unlikely that they capture all "shadow" activities, so they can be seen as providing lower bound estimates. They are unable to provide estimates of the development and growth of the shadow economy over a longer period of time. As already argued, they have, however, at least one considerable advantage – they can provide detailed information about shadow economy activities and the structure and composition of those who work in the shadow economy. 6.2 Indirect Approaches These approaches, which are also called "indicator" approaches, are mostly macroeconomic ones and use various economic and other indicators that contain information about the development of the shadow economy (over time). Currently there are five indicators that leave some "traces" of the shadow economy. 6.2.1 The Discrepancy between National Expenditure and Income Statistics This approach is based on discrepancies between income and expenditure statistics. In national accounting the income measure of GNP should be equal to the expenditure measure of GNP. Thus, if an independent estimate of the expenditure site of the national accounts is available, the gap between the expenditure measure and the income measure can be used as an indicator of the extent of the black economy.37) Since national accounts statisticians are 36) In the United States, IRS (1979, 1983), Simon and Witte (1982), Witte (1987), Clotefelter (1983), and Feige (1986). For a more detailed discussion, see Dallago (1990) and Thomas (1992). 37) See, e.g., Franz (1983) for Austria; MacAfee (1980) O’Higgins (1989) and Smith (1985), for Great Britain; Petersen (1982) and Del Boca (1981) for Germany; Park (1979) for the United States. For a critical survey, see Thomas (1992). 31.07.07, C:\ShadEconomyCorruption_July2007.doc 39 anxious to minimize this discrepancy, the initial discrepancy or first estimate, rather than the published discrepancy, should be employed as an estimate of the shadow economy. If all the components of the expenditure site are measured without error, then this approach would indeed yield a good estimate of the scale of the shadow economy. Unfortunately, however, this is not the case. Instead, the discrepancy reflects all omissions and errors everywhere in the national accounts statistics as well as the shadow economy activity. These estimates may therefore be very crude and of questionable reliability.38) 6.2.2 The Discrepancy between the Official and Actual Labour Force A decline in participation of the labour force in the official economy can be seen as an indication of increased activity in the shadow economy. If total labour force participation is assumed to be constant, then a decreasing official rate of participation can be seen as an indicator of an increase in the activities in the shadow economy, ceteris paribus.39) One weakness of this method is that differences in the rate of participation may also have other causes. Also, people can work in the shadow economy and have a job in the "official’ economy. Therefore such estimates may be viewed as weak indicators of the size and development of the shadow economy. 6.2.3 The Transactions Approach This approach has been most fully developed by Feige.40) It is based upon the assumption that there is a constant relation over time between the volume of transaction and official GNP, as summarized by the well-known Fisherian quantity equation, or M*V = p*T (with M = money, V = velocity, p = prices, and T = total transactions). Assumptions also have to be made about the velocity of money and about the relationships between the value of total transactions (p*T) and total (=official + unofficial) nominal GNP. Relating total nominal GNP to total transactions, the GNP of the shadow economy can be calculated by subtracting the official GNP from total nominal GNP. However, to derive figures for the shadow economy, one must also assume a base year in which there is no shadow economy and therefore the ratio of p*T 38) A related approach is pursued by Pissarides and Weber (1988), who use micro data from household budget surveys to estimate the extent of income understatement by self-employed. 39) Such studies have been made for Italy, see e.g., Contini (1981) and Del Boca (1981); for the United States, see O’Neill (1983), for a critical survey, see again Thomas (1992). 40) For an extended description of this approach, see Feige (1996); for a further application for the Netherlands, Boeschoten and Fase (1984), and for Germany, Langfeldt (1984). 31.07.07, C:\ShadEconomyCorruption_July2007.doc 40 to total nominal (official = total) GNP was "normal" and would have been constant over time, if there had been no shadow economy. This method, too, has several weaknesses, such as the required assumptions of a base year with no shadow economy, and of a "normal" ratio of transactions to nominal GNP. Moreover, to obtain reliable shadow economy estimates, precise figures of the total volume of transactions should be available, and this availability might be especially difficult to achieve for cash transactions, because they depend, among other factors, on the durability of bank notes in terms of the quality of the paper on which they are printed.41) Also, the assumption is made that all variations in the ratio between the total value of transaction and the officially measured GNP are due to the shadow economy. This means that a considerable amount of data is required in order to eliminate financial transactions from "pure" cross payments, which are legal and have nothing to do with the shadow economy. In general, although this approach is theoretically attractive, the empirical requirements necessary to obtain reliable estimates are so difficult to fulfil that its application may lead to doubtful results. 6.2.4 The Currency Demand Approach The currency demand approach was first used by Cagan (1958), who calculated a correlation of the currency demand and the tax pressure (as one cause of the shadow economy) for the United States over the period 1919 to 1955. 20 years later, Gutmann (1977) used the same approach but without any statistical procedures. Cagan’s approach was further developed by Tanzi (1980, 1983), who econometrically estimated a currency demand function for the United States for the period 1929 to 1980 in order to calculate the shadow economy. His approach assumes that shadow (or hidden) transactions are undertaken in the form of cash payments, so as to leave no observable traces for the authorities. An increase in the size of the shadow economy will therefore increase the demand for currency. To isolate the resulting "excess" demand for currency, an equation for currency demand is econometrically estimated over time. All conventional possible factors, such as the development of income, payment habits, interest rates, and so on, are controlled. Additionally, such variables as the direct and indirect tax burden, government regulation and the complexity of the tax system, which are assumed to be the major factors causing people to work in the shadow economy, are included 41) For a detailed criticism of the transaction approach see Boeschoten and Fase (1984), Frey and Pommerehne (1984), Kirchgaessner (1984), Tanzi (1982a,b, 1986), Dallago (1990), Thomas (1986, 1992, 1999), Giles (1999a), Pederson (2003), and Janisch and Brümmerhoff (2005) and Breusch (2005a, 2005b). 31.07.07, C:\ShadEconomyCorruption_July2007.doc 41 in the estimation equation. The basic regression equation for the currency demand, proposed by Tanzi (1983), is the following: ln (C / M2)t = βO + β1 ln (1 + TW)t + β2 ln (WS / Y)t + β3 ln Rt + β4 ln (Y / N)t + ut with β1 > 0, β2 > 0, β3 < 0, β4 > 0 where ln denotes natural logarithms, C / M2 is the ratio of cash holdings to current and deposit accounts, TW is a weighted average tax rate (to proxy changes in the size of the shadow economy), WS / Y is a proportion of wages and salaries in national income (to capture changing payment and money holding patterns), R is the interest paid on savings deposits (to capture the opportunity cost of holding cash) and Y / N is the per capita income.42) Any "excess" increase in currency, or the amount unexplained by the conventional or normal factors (mentioned above) is then attributed to the rising tax burden and the other reasons leading people to work in the shadow economy. Figures for the size and development of the shadow economy can be calculated in a first step by comparing the difference between the development of currency when the direct and indirect tax burden (and government regulations) are held at their lowest value, and the development of currency with the current (much higher) burden of taxation and government regulations. Assuming in a second step the same income velocity for currency used in the shadow economy as for legal M1 in the official economy, the size of the shadow can be computed and compared to the official GDP. The currency demand approach is one of the most commonly used approaches. It has been applied to many OECD countries,43) but has nevertheless been criticized on various grounds.44) The most commonly raised objections to this method are: 42) The estimation of such a currency demand equation has been criticized by Thomas (1999) but part of this criticism has been considered by the work of Giles (1999a,b) and Bhattacharyya (1999), who both use the latest econometric technics. 43) See Karmann (1986 and 1990), Schneider (1997, 1998a), Johnson, Kaufmann and Zoido-Lobatón (1998a), and Williams and Windebank (1995). 44) See Thomas (1992, 1999); Feige (1986); Pozo (1996); Pedersen (2003) and Ahumada, Alvareda, Canavese A. and P. Canavese (2004); Janisch and Brümmerhof (2005); and Breusch (2005a,b). 31.07.07, C:\ShadEconomyCorruption_July2007.doc 42 (i) Not all transactions in the shadow economy are paid in cash. Isachsen and Strom (1985) used the survey method to find out that in Norway, in 1980, roughly 80% of all transactions in the hidden sector were paid in cash. The size of the total shadow economy (including barter) may thus be even larger than previously estimated. (ii) Most studies consider only one particular factor, the tax burden, as a cause of the shadow economy. But others (such as the impact of regulation, taxpayers’ attitudes toward the state, "tax morality" and so on) are not considered, because reliable data for most countries are not available. If, as seems likely, these other factors also have an impact on the extent of the hidden economy, it might again be higher than reported in most studies.45) (iii) As discussed by Garcia (1978), Park (1979), and Feige (1996), increases in currency demand deposits are due largely to a slowdown in demand deposits rather than to an increase in currency caused by activities in the shadow economy, at least in the case of the United States. (iv) Blades (1982) and Feige (1986, 1996), criticize Tanzi’s studies on the grounds that the US dollar is used as an international currency. Instead, Tanzi should have considered (and controlled) the presence of US dollars, which are used as an international currency and are held in cash abroad.46) Moreover, Frey and Pommerehne (1984) and Thomas (1986, 1992, 1999) claim that Tanzi’s parameter estimates are not very stable.47) (v) Most studies assume the same velocity of money in both types of economies. As argued by Hill and Kabir (1996) for Canada and by Klovland (1984) for the Scandinavian countries, there is already considerable uncertainty about the velocity of 45) One (weak) justification for the use of only the tax variable is that this variable has by far the strongest impact on the size of the shadow economy in the studies known to the authors. The only exception is the study by Frey and Weck-Hannemann (1984) where the variable "tax immorality" has a quantitatively larger and statistically stronger influence than the direct tax share in the model approach. In the study of Pommerehne and Schneider (1985), for the U.S., besides various tax measures, data for regulation, tax immorality, minimum wage rates are available, the tax variable has a dominating influence and contributes roughly 60-70% of the size of the shadow economy. See also Zilberfarb (1986). 46) In another study by Tanzi (1982, esp. pp. 110-113) he explicitly deals with this criticism. A very careful investigation of the amount of US-$ used abroad and the US currency used in the shadow economy and to "classical" crime activities has been undertaken by Rogoff (1998), who concludes that large denomination bills are the major driving force for the growth of the shadow economy and classical crime activities are due largely to reduced transactions costs. 47) However in studies for European countries Kirchgaessner (1983, 1984) and Schneider (1986) reach the conclusion that the estimation results for Germany, Denmark, Norway and Sweden are quite robust when using the currency demand method. Hill and Kabir (1996) find for Canada that the rise of the shadow economy varies with respect to the tax variable used; they conclude "when the theoretically best tax rates are selected and a range of plausible velocity values is used, this method estimates underground economic growth between 1964 and 1995 at between 3 and 11 percent of GDP." (Hill and Kabir [1996, p. 1553]). 31.07.07, C:\ShadEconomyCorruption_July2007.doc 43 money in the official economy, and the velocity of money in the hidden sector is even more difficult to estimate. Without knowledge about the velocity of currency in the shadow economy, one has to accept the assumption of "equal" money velocity in both sectors. (vi) Ahumada, Alvaredo, Canavese A. and P. Canavese (2004) show that the currency approach, together with the assumption of equal income velocity of money in both the reported and the hidden transaction is only correct if the income elasticity is 1. As this is not the case for most countries, the calculation has to be corrected. (vii) Finally, the assumption of no shadow economy in a base year is open to criticism. Relaxing this assumption would again imply an upward adjustment of the size of the shadow economy. 6.2.5 The Physical Input (Electricity Consumption) Method (1) The Kaufmann – Kaliberda Method48) To measure overall (official and unofficial) economic activity in an economy, Kaufmann and Kaliberda (1996) assume that electric-power consumption is regarded as the single best physical indicator of overall (or official plus unofficial) economic activity. Now, overall economic activity and electricity consumption have been empirically observed throughout the world to move in lockstep with an electricity to GDP elasticity usually close to one. This means that the growth of total electricity consumption is an indicator for growth of overall (official and unofficial) GDP. By having this proxy measurement for the overall economy and then subtracting from this overall measure the estimates of official GDP, Kaufmann and Kaliberda (1996) derive an estimate of unofficial GDP. This method is very simple and appealing. However, it can also be criticized on various grounds: (i) Not all shadow economy activities require a considerable amount of electricity (e.g. personal services), and other energy sources can be used (gas, oil, coal, etc.). Only a part of the shadow economy will be captured. (ii) Over time, there has been considerable technical progress, so that both the production and use of electricity are more efficient than in the past, and this will apply in both official and unofficial uses. 48) This method was used earlier by Lizzeri (1979), Del Boca and Forte (1982), and then was used much later by Portes (1996), Kaufmann and Kaliberda (1996), Johnson, Kaufmann and Shleifer (1997). For a critique see Lackó (1998). 31.07.07, C:\ShadEconomyCorruption_July2007.doc 44 (iii) There may be considerable differences or changes in the elasticity of electricity/GDP across countries and over time.49) (2) The Lackó Method Lackó (1996, 1998, 1999, 2000) assumes that a certain part of the shadow economy is associated with the household consumption of electricity. This part comprises the so-called household production, do-it-yourself activities, and other non registered production and services. Lackó further assumes that in countries where the portion of the shadow economy associated with the household electricity consumption is high, the rest of the hidden economy (or the part Lackó cannot measure) will also be high. Lackó (1996, pp.19 ff.) assumes that in each country a part of the household consumption of electricity is used in the shadow economy. Lackó’s approach (1998, p.133) can be described by the following two equations: ln Ei with = α1 ln Ci + α2 ln PRi + α3 Gi + α4 Qi + α5 Hi + ui (1) α1 > 0, α2 < 0, α3 > 0, α4 < 0, α5 > 0 = β1 Ti + β2 (Si – Ti) + β3 Di Hi (2) with β1 > 0, β2 < 0, β3 > 0 where i: the number assigned to the country, Ei: per capita household electricity consumption in country i in Mtoe, Ci: per capita real consumption of households without the consumption of electricity in country i in US dollars (at purchasing power parity), PRi: the real price of consumption of 1 kWh of residential electricity in US dollars (at purchasing power parity), Gi: the relative frequency of months with the need of heating in houses in country i, Qi: the ratio of energy sources other than electricity energy to all energy sources in household energy consumption, Hi: the per capita output of the hidden economy, Ti: the ratio of the sum of paid personal income, corporate profit and taxes on goods and services to GDP, Si: the ratio of public social welfare expenditures to GDP, and 49) Johnson, Kaufmann and Shleifer (1997) make an attempt to adjust for changes in the elasticity of electricity/GDP. 31.07.07, C:\ShadEconomyCorruption_July2007.doc 45 Di: the sum of dependants over 14 years and of inactive earners, both per 100 active earners. In a cross country study, Lackó econometrically estimates equation (1) substituting Hi by equation (2). The econometric estimation results can then be used to establish an ordering of the countries with respect to electricity use in their respective shadow economies. For the calculation of the actual size (value added) of the shadow economy, Lackó must, furthermore, know how much GDP is produced by one unit of electricity in the shadow economy of each country. Since these data are not known, she takes the result of one of the known shadow economy estimations carried out for a market economy with another approach for the early 1990s, and she applies this proportion to the other countries. Lackó used the shadow economy of the United States as such a base (the shadow economy value of 10.5% of GDP taken from Morris (1993)), and then she calculates the size of the shadow economy for other countries. Lackó’s method is also open to criticism: (i) Not all shadow economy activities require a considerable amount of electricity and other energy sources can be used. (ii) Shadow economy activities do not take place only in the household sector. (iii) It is doubtful whether the ratio of social welfare expenditures can be used as the explanatory factor for the shadow economy, especially in transition and developing countries. (iv) It is questionable which is the most reliable base value of the shadow economy in order to calculate the size of the shadow economy for all other countries, especially for the transition and developing countries. 6.3 The Model Approach50 All methods described so far that are designed to estimate the size and development of the shadow economy consider just one indicator that "must" capture all effects of the shadow economy. However, it is obvious that shadow economy effects show up simultaneously in the production, labour, and money markets. An even more important critique is that the causes 50) This part is derived from a longer study by Aigner, Schneider, and Ghosh (1988, p. 303), applying this approach for the United States over time; for Germany this approach has been applied by Karmann (1986 and 1990). The pioneers of this approach are Weck (1983), Frey and Weck-Hannemann (1984), who applied this approach to cross-section data from the 24 OECD countries for various years. Before turning to this approach they developed the concept of "soft modeling" (Frey, Weck, and Pommerehne (1982), Frey and Weck (1983a and 1983b)), an approach which has been used to provide a ranking of the relative size of the shadow economy 31.07.07, C:\ShadEconomyCorruption_July2007.doc 46 that determine the size of the shadow economy are taken into account only in some of the monetary approach studies that usually consider one cause, the burden of taxation. The model approach explicitly considers multiple causes leading to the existence and growth of the shadow economy, as well as the multiple effects of the shadow economy over time. The empirical method used is quite different from those used so far. It is based on the statistical theory of unobserved variables, which considers multiple causes and multiple indicators of the phenomenon to be measured. For the estimation, a factor-analytic approach is used to measure the hidden economy as an unobserved variable over time. The unknown coefficients are estimated in a set of structural equations within which the "unobserved" variable cannot be measured directly. The DYMIMIC (dynamic multiple-indicators multiplecauses) model consists in general of two parts, with the measurement model linking the unobserved variables to observed indicators.51) The structural equations model specifies causal relationships among the unobserved variables. In this case, there is one unobserved variable, or the size of the shadow economy; this is assumed to be influenced by a set of indicators for the shadow economy’s size, thus capturing the structural dependence of the shadow economy on variables that may be useful in predicting its movement and size in the future. The interaction over time between the causes Zit (i = 1, 2, …, k) the size of the shadow economy Xt, in time t and the indicators Yjt (j = 1, 2, …, p) is shown in Figure 6.1. Figure 6.1: Development of the shadow economy over time. Causes Xt-1 Indicators ↓ Z1t Z2t ... Y1t Development of the shadow economy over time Y2t Xt ... Zkt Ypt in different countries. 51) The latest papers dealing extensively with the DYMIMIC or MIMIC approach, its development and its weaknesses are from Del’Anno (2003) and the excellent study by Giles and Tedds (2002), as well as Breusch (2005a, 2005b), Schneider (2005), and Pickhardt and Sarda-Pous (2006). 31.07.07, C:\ShadEconomyCorruption_July2007.doc 47 There is a large body of literature52) on the possible causes and indicators of the shadow economy, in which the following three types of causes are distinguished: Causes (i) The burden of direct and indirect taxation, both actual and perceived. A rising burden of taxation provides a strong incentive to work in the shadow economy. (ii) The burden of regulation as proxy for all other state activities. It is assumed that increases in the burden of regulation give a strong incentive to enter the shadow economy. (iii) The "tax morality" (citizens’ attitudes toward the state), which describes the readiness of individuals (at least partly) to leave their official occupations and enter the shadow economy: it is assumed that a declining tax morality tends to increase the size of the shadow economy.53) Indicators A change in the size of the shadow economy may be reflected in the following indicators: (i) Development of monetary indicators. If activities in the shadow economy rise, additional monetary transactions are required. (ii) Development of the labour market. Increasing participation of workers in the hidden sector results in a decrease in participation in the official economy. Similarly, increased activities in the hidden sector may be expected to be reflected in shorter working hours in the official economy. (iii) Development of the production market. An increase in the shadow economy means that inputs (especially labour) move out of the official economy (at least partly), and this displacement might have a depressing effect on the official growth rate of the economy. The latest use of the model approach has been undertaken by Giles (1999a, 1999b, 1999c) and by Giles, Tedds and Werkneh (2002), Giles and Tedds (2002), Chatterjee, Chaudhury and Schneider (2006), Bajada and Schneider (2005), and Pickhardt and Sarda-Pous (2006). They 52) Thomas (1992); Schneider (1994a, 1997, 2003, 2005); Pozo (1996); Johnson, Kaufmann and Zoido-Lobatón (1998a, 1998b); Giles (1997a, 1997b, 1999a, 1999b, 1999c); Giles and Tedds (2002), Giles, Tedds and Werkneh (2002), Del’Anno (2003) and Del’Anno and Schneider (2004). 53) When applying this approach for European countries, Frey and Weck-Hannemann (1984) had difficulty in obtaining reliable data for the cause series, besides the ones for the direct and indirect tax burden. Hence, their study was criticized by Helberger and Knepel (1988), who argue that the results were unstable with respect to changing variables in the model and over the years. 31.07.07, C:\ShadEconomyCorruption_July2007.doc 48 basically estimate a comprehensive (sometime dynamic) MIMIC model to get a time series index of the hidden/measured output of New Zealand, Canada, Germany, India or Australia, and then estimate a separate "cash-demand model" to obtain a benchmark for converting this index into percentage units. Unlike earlier empirical studies of the hidden economy, they paid proper attention to the non-stationary, and possible co-integration of time serious data in both models. Again this DYMIMIC model treats hidden output as a latent variable, and uses several (measurable) causal variables and indicator variables. The former include measures of the average and marginal tax rates, inflation, real income and the degree of regulation in the economy. The latter include changes in the (male) labour force participation rate and in the cash/money supply ratio. In their cash-demand equation they allow for different velocities of currency circulation in the hidden and recorded economies. Their cash-demand equation is not used as an input to determine the variation in the hidden economy over time – it is used only to obtain the long-run average value of hidden/measured output, so that the index for this ratio predicted by the DYMIMIC model can be used to calculate a level and the percentage units of the shadow economy. Overall, this latest combination of the currency demand and DYMIMIC approach clearly shows that some progress in the estimation technique of the shadow economy has been achieved and a number of critical points have been overcome. However, objections can also be raised against the (DY)MIMIC method, i.e.: (1) instability in the estimated coefficients with respect to sample size changes, (2) instability in the estimated coefficients with respect to alternative specifications, (3) difficulty of obtaining reliable data on cause variables other than tax variables, and (4) the reliability of the variables grouping into "causes" and "indicators" in explaining the variability of the shadow economy. 6.4 Summarizing the Critical Remarks In table 6.2 some more general weaknesses/criticisms of the different methods of estimating the shadow economy are summarized. Table 6.2 clearly shows that each method has its strength and weaknesses and that we are far away from having an ideal or most preferred estimation method. When undertaking the difficult and challenging task of estimating the shadow economy, all methods have weaknesses and it is important to report and to consider them, and to treat the size and development of shadow economy with great care. 31.07.07, C:\ShadEconomyCorruption_July2007.doc 49 Table 6.2: Some critical Points of the Different Estimation Methods 1. Surveys (1) Quite often only households or only partly firms are considered (2) Non-responses and/or incorrect responses 2. Estimations of national account statisticians (quite often the discrepancy method): (1) Combination of meso estimates/assumptions (2) Often not published (3) Documentation and procedures often not public 3. Monetary and/or electricity methods: (1) Some estimates are very high (2) Are the assumptions plausible? (3) Breakdown by sector or industry possible? 4. DYMIMIC method (1) only relative coefficients, no absolute values (2) estimations quite often highly sensitive with respect to changes in the data. 6.5 The Size and Development of the Shadow Economies of 145 Countries over 1999/2000 to 2004/2005 Finally, the results of the size and development of the shadow economies of 145 countries are shown (and the countries are listed in alphabetical order) in table 6.3. Table 6.3: The Size of the Shadow Economy of 145 Countries Shadow Economy (in % of official GDP) using the DYMIMIC and Currency Demand Method No. 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 Country Albania Algeria Angola Argentina Armenia Australia Austria Azerbaijan Bangladesh Belarus Belgium 1999/00 33.4 34.1 43.2 25.4 46.3 14.3 9.8 60.6 35.6 48.1 22.2 2001/02 34.6 35.0 44.1 27.1 47.8 14.1 10.6 61.1 36.5 49.3 22.0 31.07.07, C:\ShadEconomyCorruption_July2007.doc 2002/03 35.3 35.6 45.2 28.9 49.1 13.5 10.9 61.3 37.7 50.4 21.0 2003/04 35.0 34.8 45.3 28.6 48.4 13.1 10.1 60.8 38.3 50.5 20.4 2004/05 34.3 33.9 45.0 27.2 47.6 12.8 9.3 59.4 38.0 50.8 19.6 50 Shadow Economy (in % of official GDP) using the DYMIMIC and Currency Demand Method Country 12 Benin 13 Bhutan 14 Bolivia Bosnia and 15 Herzegovina 16 Botswana 17 Brazil 18 Bulgaria 19 Burkina Faso 20 Burundi 21 Cambodia 22 Cameroon 23 Canada 24 Central African Republic 25 Chad 26 Chile 27 China 28 Colombia 29 Congo, Dem. Rep. 30 Costa Rica 31 Cote d'Ivoire 32 Croatia 33 Czech Republic 34 Denmark 35 Dominican Republic 36 Ecuador 37 Egypt, Arabian Republic 38 El Salvador 39 Estonia 40 Ethiopia 41 Fiji 42 Finland 43 France 44 Georgia 45 Germany 46 Ghana 47 Greece 48 Guatemala 49 Guinea 50 Haiti 51 Honduras 52 Hong Kong, China 53 Hungary 54 India 55 Indonesia 56 Iran, Islamic Republic 57 Ireland 58 Israel 59 Italy 60 Jamaica No. 1999/00 47.3 29.4 67.1 2001/02 48.2 30.5 68.1 2002/03 49.1 31.7 68.3 2003/04 49.3 32.7 68.0 2004/05 49.8 33.1 67.2 34.1 33.4 39.8 36.9 41.4 36.9 50.1 32.8 16.0 44.3 46.2 19.8 13.1 39.1 48.0 26.2 43.2 33.4 19.1 18.0 32.1 34.4 35.1 46.3 38.4 40.3 33.6 18.1 15.2 67.3 16.0 41.9 28.7 51.5 39.6 55.4 49.6 16.6 25.1 23.1 19.4 18.9 15.9 21.9 27.1 36.4 35.4 33.9 40.9 37.1 42.6 37.6 51.3 33.7 15.8 45.4 47.1 20.3 14.4 41.3 48.8 27.0 44.3 34.2 19.6 17.9 33.4 35.1 36.0 47.1 39.2 41.4 34.3 18.0 15.0 67.6 16.3 42.7 28.5 51.9 40.8 57.1 50.8 17.1 25.7 24.2 21.8 19.4 15.7 22.8 27.0 37.8 36.7 34.6 42.3 38.3 43.3 38.7 52.4 34.9 15.2 46.1 48.0 20.9 15.6 43.4 49.7 27.8 45.2 35.4 20.1 17.3 34.1 36.7 36.9 48.3 40.1 42.1 35.1 17.4 14.5 68.0 16.8 43.6 28.2 52.4 41.3 58.6 51.6 17.2 26.2 25.6 22.9 19.9 15.3 23.9 25.7 38.9 36.2 34.2 42.6 37.4 43.8 39.4 52.9 34.4 14.8 46.3 48.4 20.3 16.1 43.0 50.4 27.1 45.4 34.7 19.2 16.7 34.4 36.1 36.3 48.1 39.1 42.7 34.6 16.4 13.8 67.3 16.1 43.8 27.4 51.1 41.7 59.3 50.8 16.4 25.3 25.9 23.6 20.2 14.8 23.2 24.8 39.2 35.3 33.8 41.8 36.5 43.1 39.7 52.2 33.6 14.1 46.9 47.8 19.4 16.6 42.7 50.8 26.3 44.7 34.1 18.3 16.1 34.8 35.2 35.4 47.2 38.2 42.0 33.8 15.8 13.2 66.4 15.3 43.2 26.3 50.3 41.0 59.6 49.3 15.6 24.3 25.1 24.0 19.7 14.1 22.6 23.2 38.4 31.07.07, C:\ShadEconomyCorruption_July2007.doc 51 Shadow Economy (in % of official GDP) using the DYMIMIC and Currency Demand Method No. 61 62 63 64 65 66 67 68 69 70 71 72 73 74 75 76 77 78 79 80 81 82 83 84 85 86 87 88 89 90 91 92 93 94 95 96 97 98 99 100 101 102 103 104 105 106 107 108 109 110 Country Japan Jordan Kazakhstan Kenya Kiribati Korea, Republic Kuwait Kyrgyz Republic Lao PDR Latvia Lebanon Lesotho Lithuania Macedonia, FYR Madagascar Malawi Malaysia Maldives Mali Marshall Islands Mauritania Mexico Micronesia, Fed. Sts. Moldova Mongolia Morocco Mozambique Namibia Nepal Netherlands New Zealand Nicaragua Niger Nigeria Norway Oman Pakistan Palau Panama Papua New Guinea Paraguay Peru Philippines Poland Portugal Puerto Rico Republic of Congo Romania Russian Federation Rwanda 1999/00 11.2 19.4 43.2 34.3 34.1 27.5 20.1 39.8 30.6 39.9 34.1 31.3 30.3 34.1 39.6 40.3 31.1 30.3 42.3 28.1 36.1 30.1 31.3 45.1 18.4 36.4 40.3 31.4 38.4 13.1 12.8 45.2 41.9 57.9 19.1 18.9 36.8 28.4 64.1 36.1 27.4 59.9 43.4 27.6 22.7 28.4 48.2 34.4 46.1 40.3 2001/02 11.1 20.5 44.1 35.1 35.0 28.1 20.7 40.3 31.9 40.7 35.6 32.4 31.4 35.1 40.4 41.2 31.6 31.4 43.9 29.0 37.2 31.8 32.1 47.3 19.6 37.1 41.3 32.6 39.7 13.0 12.6 46.9 42.6 58.6 19.0 19.4 37.9 29.2 65.1 37.3 29.2 60.3 44.5 28.2 22.5 29.4 49.1 36.1 47.5 41.4 31.07.07, C:\ShadEconomyCorruption_July2007.doc 2002/03 10.8 21.6 45.2 36.0 35.3 28.8 21.6 41.2 33.4 41.3 36.2 33.3 32.6 36.3 41.6 42.1 32.2 32.0 44.7 29.6 38.0 33.2 33.2 49.4 20.4 37.9 42.4 33.4 40.8 12.6 12.3 48.2 43.8 59.4 18.4 19.8 38.7 30.0 65.3 38.6 31.4 60.9 45.6 28.9 21.9 30.7 50.1 37.4 48.7 42.2 2003/04 9.4 21.2 45.4 35.4 34.8 28.2 21.2 41.4 33.9 40.4 36.5 32.8 31.3 36.8 41.9 42.7 32.0 31.6 44.0 28.7 37.4 32.6 32.6 49.5 20.6 37.3 42.9 33.0 40.2 12.0 11.6 48.8 44.1 59.6 17.6 19.2 39.2 29.2 64.1 38.0 32.4 59.1 45.1 28.2 21.1 29.6 50.5 36.2 48.2 42.4 2004/05 8.8 20.4 44.6 34.8 34.0 27.6 20.7 40.6 33.2 39.4 37.1 32.3 30.2 36.9 41.2 41.9 31.4 30.9 43.2 27.9 36.8 31.7 31.9 49.1 21.2 36.7 43.5 32.4 39.3 11.1 10.9 48.1 44.2 59.5 16.8 18.6 39.5 28.4 62.2 37.3 33.1 58.2 44.3 27.3 20.4 28.2 51.1 35.4 47.3 41.6 52 Shadow Economy (in % of official GDP) using the DYMIMIC and Currency Demand Method Country 111 Samoa 112 Saudi Arabia 113 Senegal 114 Serbia and Montenegro 115 Sierra Leone 116 Singapore 117 Slovak Republic 118 Slovenia 119 Solomon Islands 120 South Africa 121 Spain 122 Sri Lanka 123 Sweden 124 Switzerland 125 Syrian Arab Republic 126 Taiwan, China 127 Tanzania 128 Thailand 129 Togo 130 Tonga 131 Tunisia 132 Turkey 133 Uganda 134 Ukraine 135 United Arab Emirates 136 United Kingdom 137 United States 138 Uruguay 139 Uzbekistan 140 Vanuatu 141 Venezuela, RB 142 Vietnam 143 Yemen, Rep. 144 Zambia 145 Zimbabwe Unweighted Average No. 1999/00 31.4 18.4 45.1 36.4 41.7 13.1 18.9 27.1 33.4 28.4 22.7 44.6 19.2 8.6 19.3 25.4 58.3 52.6 35.1 35.1 38.4 32.1 43.1 52.2 26.4 12.7 8.7 51.1 34.1 30.9 33.6 15.6 27.4 48.9 59.4 33.6 2001/02 32.6 19.1 46.8 37.3 42.8 13.4 19.3 28.3 34.5 29.1 22.5 45.9 19.1 9.4 20.4 26.6 59.4 53.4 39.2 36.3 39.1 33.2 44.6 53.6 27.1 12.5 8.7 51.4 35.7 31.7 35.1 16.9 28.4 49.7 61.0 34.5 2002/03 33.5 19.7 47.5 39.1 43.9 13.7 20.2 29.4 35.3 29.5 22.0 47.2 18.3 9.4 21.6 27.7 60.2 54.1 40.4 37.4 39.9 34.3 45.4 54.7 27.8 12.2 8.4 51.9 37.2 32.5 36.7 17.9 29.1 50.8 63.2 35.2 2003/04 33.1 19.3 47.8 38.2 44.1 13.0 19.1 28.2 34.6 29.0 21.2 48.3 17.2 9.0 21.7 27.0 59.1 54.3 40.6 36.8 39.4 33.9 45.8 54.9 27.2 11.7 8.2 50.8 36.3 32.0 36.1 16.9 28.2 50.2 63.9 34.9 2004/05 32.8 18.4 48.2 37.3 44.3 12.1 18.2 27.3 34.0 28.2 20.5 48.8 16.3 8.5 21.2 26.3 58.2 53.6 39.4 35.8 38.3 33.2 44.9 55.3 26.5 10.3 7.9 49.2 35.4 31.4 35.4 16.1 27.3 49.3 64.6 34.3 Source: Own calculations. 31.07.07, C:\ShadEconomyCorruption_July2007.doc 53 7 Appendix 2: Definition of the variables and data sources (1) GDP per capita on PPP basis GDP per capita is based on purchasing power parity [PPP]. PPP GDP is gross domestic product converted to international dollars using purchasing power parity rates. An international dollar has the same purchasing power over GDP as the U.S. dollar has in the United States. GDP is the sum of gross value added by all resident producers in the economy plus any product taxes and minus any subsidies not included in the value of the products. It is calculated without making deductions for depreciation of fabricated assets or for depletion and degradation of natural resources. Data are in current dollars. Source: World Bank, International Comparison Programme database. (2) Annual GDP per capita Growth Rate Out of this GDP per capita values for the observed 145 countries the independent variable annual GDP per capita Growth Rate has been calculated using the formula Per Capita Growth = (GDPpct − GDPpct −1 ) GDPpct −1 Source: World Bank, International Comparison Programme database; own calculation by authors. (3) Shadow Economy The variable Shadow Economy is defined as the informal sector [shadow economy] in percent of official GDP. The estimations for the size of the shadow economy are undertaken using the DYMIMIC and the currency demand approaches; using the values calculated in section 3. This variable is available for five points in time namely the years 1999/00, 2001/02, 2002/03, 2003/04 and 2004/05. Source: Own calculation by the author. (4) Share of Direct Taxation (in % of GDP) Source: OECD, Paris 2003, Taxing Wages and World Bank (Washington D.C.), 2003, Governance Indicators. 31.07.07, C:\ShadEconomyCorruption_July2007.doc 54 (5) Share of Indirect Taxation and Custom Duties in % of GDP Source: See Share of Direct Taxation. (6) Burden of State Regulation Burden of State regulation, index of regulation, where a score of 1 signifies an economic environment most conductive to economic freedom, whereas a score of 5 signifies least economic freedom. Source: Heritage Foundation 2005, Index of Economic Freedom, Washington, D.C. (7) Employment Quota (in % of population between 18 and 64) Source: OECD, Paris, various years, Employment Outlook. (8) Unemployment Quota (% of unemployed in the working force) Source: OECD various years, Employment Outlook. (9) Change of Currency per Capita, Annual Rate of Currency per Capita Source: World Bank National Accounts Data and OECD National Accounts Data Files, Washington and Paris, various years. (10) Tax Morale (Index) Source: European Values Study, EUROPEAN VALUES STUDY, various years/Release 1, The Netherlands, Germany: Tilburg University, Zentralarchiv für Empirische Sozialforschung, Cologne (ZA), Netherlands Institute for Scientific Information Services (NIWI), Amsterdam [producer], 2006. Germany: Zentralarchiv für Empirische Sozialforschung, Cologne [distributor], 2006. Inglehart, Ronald et.al. World Values Surveys and European Values Surveys, 1981-1984, 1990-1993 and 1995-1997 [Computer file]. (11) Quality of Institutions index =0 lowest quality, =100 highest quality, Source World Bank, various years. (12) Social Security Burden Definition: social security payments (employers and employees) in % of GDP, Source OECD, Paris, various years. 31.07.07, C:\ShadEconomyCorruption_July2007.doc 55 (13) Quality of State Institutions Quality of state institutions, World Bank rule of law index, ranges from -3 to +3, with higher scores showing better environments, i.e. the higher the score the better is the rule of law in that respective country. Source: Index development; Kaufmann, D.; Kraay, A. and M. Mastruzzi, 2003, Governments Matters III: Governments Indicators for 1996/2002, World Bank Policy Research Working Papers 3106, World Bank, Washington D.C.; source index World Bank, Washington, various years. 31.07.07, C:\ShadEconomyCorruption_July2007.doc 56 8 References Ahumada, Hildegard, Alvaredo, Facundo, Canavese Alfredo. and Paula. Canavese (2004): The demand for currency approach and the size of the shadow economy: A critical assessment, Discussion Paper, Delta Ecole. Normale Superieure, Paris. Adam, Markus, C. and Victor Ginsburgh, (1985), The effects of irregular markets on macroeconomic policy: Some estimates for Belgium, European Economic Review, 29/1, pp. 15-33. Aigner, Dennis; Schneider, Friedrich and Damayanti Ghosh (1988): Me and my shadow: estimating the size of the US hidden economy from time series data, in W. A. Barnett; E. R. Berndt and H. White (eds.): Dynamic econometric modeling, Cambridge (Mass.): Cambridge University Press, pp. 224-243. Alexeev, Michael and Pyle, William (2003): A note on measuring the unofficial economy in the former Soviet Republics, Economics of Transition, 11/1, p.1-23. Alderslade, Jamie, John Talmage and Yusef Freeman (2006): Measuring the Informal Economy: One Neighborhood at a Time, Discussion Paper, The Brooking Institution Metropolitan Policy Program, Washington D.C., September 2006. Alm, James, Martinez-Vazquez, Jorge and Friedrich Schneider (2004), ‘Sizing the problem of the hard-to-tax’, Working Paper, Georgia State University: USA. Andreoni, James; Erard, Brian, and Jonathan Feinstein (1998): Tax compliance. Journal of Economic Literature, 36, pp. 818-860. Asea, Patrick K. (1996): The informal sector: baby or bath water? Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 45., pp. 163-171. Bajada Christopher (2002): Australia’s Cash Economy: A Troubling Issue for Policy Makers. Aldershort (Great Britain), Ashgate Publishing Company. Bajada, Christopher and Friedrich Schneider (2003): The size and development of the shadow economies in the Asia-Pacific, Discussion Paper, Department of Economics, University of Linz, Austria, published in the Asian Pacific Economic Journal, 2005. Bajada, Christopher and Friedrich Schneider (2005): Size, Causes and Consequences of the Underground Economy: An International Perspective, Aldershot (GB): Ashgate Publishing Company. Barro, Robert. J. and Sala-i-Martin, Xavier. (1995), ‘Economic Growth’, McGraw-Hill: USA. Belev, Boyan (2003): The informal economy in the EU Accession Countries: Size, scope, trends and challenges to the process of EU enlargement, Center for Study of Democracy, Sofia. Bhattacharyya, D.K. (1999): On the economic rationale of estimating the hidden economy, The Economic Journal 109/456, pp. 348-359. Blades, Derek (1982): "The hidden economy and the national accounts", OECD (Occasional Studies), Paris, pp. 28-44. Boeschoten, Werner C. and Marcel M.G. Fase (1984): The Volume of Payments and the Informal Economy in the Netherlands 1965-1982, M. Nijhoff, Dordrecht. Brehm, J.W. (1966): A Theory of Psychological Reactance. New York (Academic Press). Brehm, J.W. (1972): Responses to Loss of Freedom. A Theory of Psychological Reactance. Morristown (General Learning Press). Breusch, Trevor (2005a): "The Canadian Underground Economy: An Examination of Giles and Tedds", Canadian Tax Journal, 53/2, pp.367-391. Breusch, Trevor (2005b): "Estimating the Underground Economy, Using MIMIC Models", Working Paper, National University of Australia, Canberra, Australia. Brueck, Tilman, John B. Haisten-DeNew and Klaus F. Zimmermann (2006): Creating low-skilled Jobs by Subsidizing Market Contracted Household Work, Applied Economics 38/4, pp.899-911. Buehn, Andreas, Karmann, Alexander an Friedrich Schneider (2007), Shadow Economy and Do-it-yourself Activities: The German Case, Discussion Paper, Department of Economics, University of Linz. Cagan, Phillip (1958): "The demand for currency relative to the total money supply," Journal of Political Economy, 66:3, pp. 302-328. Chatterjee, S.; Chaudhury K. and F. Schneider (2006): The size and development of the Indian shadow economy and a comparison with other 18 Asian countries: An empirical investigation, forthcoming in the Journal of Development Economics, April 2006. 31.07.07, C:\ShadEconomyCorruption_July2007.doc 57 Chen, Martha (2004): Rethinking the informal economy: Linkages with the formal economy and the formal regulatory environment, paper presented at the EGDI-WIDR Conference ‘unleashing human potential: linking the informal and formal sectors, Helsinki, Finland, 2004. Choi, J. and M. Thum, 2004, Corruption and the shadow economy, International Economic Review 12/4, pp.308-342. Clotefelter, Charles T. (1983): Tax evasion and tax rates: An analysis of individual return, Review of Economic Statistics, 65/3, pp. 363-373. Contini, Bruno (1981): Labour market segmentation and the development of the parallel economy – the Italian experience, Oxford Economic Papers, 33/4, pp. 401-12. Dallago, Bruno (1990): The irregular economy: The "underground economy" and the "black labour market", Dartmouth (U.K.), Publishing Company. Del’Anno, Roberto (2003): Estimating the shadow economy in Italy: A structural equation approach, Discussion Paper, Department of Economics and Statistics, University of Salerno. Del’Anno, Roberto and Friedrich Schneider (2004): The shadow economy of Italy and other OECD countries: What do we know?, Linz: University of Linz, Department of Economics, Discussion Paper, published in Journal of Public Finance and Public Choice, 2005. Del’Anno, Roberto and Friedrich Schneider (2005): Estimating the Underground Economy by Using MIMIC Models: A Response to T.Breuschs Critic, Discussion Paper, Department of Economics, University of Linz, Linz. Del Boca, Daniela. (1981): Parallel economy and allocation of time, Micros (Quarterly Journal of Microeconomics), 4/2, pp. 13-18. Del Boca, Daniela and Francesco Forte (1982): Recent empirical surveys and theoretical interpretations of the parallel economy in Italy; Tanzi, Vito (1982) (ed.): The underground economy in the United States and abroad, Lexington (Mass.), Lexington, pp. 160-178. Dreher, Axel; Christos Kotsogiannis and Steve McCorriston, 2005a, How do Institutions Affect Corruption and the Shadow Economy? University of Konstanz and University of Exeter, mimeo. Dreher, Axel; Christos Kotsogiannis and Steve McCorriston, 2005b, Corruption around the World: Evidence from a Structural Model, University of Konstanz and University of Exeter, mimeo. Dreher, Axel and Lars-H.R. Siemers, 2005, The Intriguing Nexus Between Corruption and Capital Account Restrictions, KOF Working Paper 113, Swiss Federal Institute of Technology (ETH Zurich). Dreher, Axel and Friedrich Schneider (2006): Corruption and Shadow Economy: An Empirical Analysis, Discussion Paper, Department of Economies, University of Linz, 2006. Enste, Dominik and Friedrich Schneider (2006), Wie groß ist die Schattenwirtschaft? Des Rätsels Lösung, Wirtschaftsdienst – Zeitschrift für Wirtschaftspolitik 86/2, pp.185-191. Feige, Edgar L. (1986): A re-examination of the "Underground Economy" in the United States. IMF Staff Papers, 33/ 4, pp. 768-781. Feige, Edgar L. (1989) (ed.): The Underground Economies. Tax Evasion and Information Distortion. Cambridge, New York, Melbourne, Cambridge University Press. Feige, Edgar L. (1994): The underground economy and the currency enigma, Supplement to Public Finance/ Finances Publiques, 49, pp. 119-136. Feige, Edgar L. (1996): Overseas holdings of U.S. currency and the underground economy, in: Pozo, Susan (ed.): Exploring the Underground Economy. Kalamazoo, Michigan, pp. 5-62. Flaming, Daniel; Breut Hayolamak and Pascale Jossart (2005), Hopeful Workers, Marginal Jobs: LA’s Off-TheBooks Labour Force, Economic Roundtable, Los Angeles, CA, 2005. Fleming, M.H.; Roman, J. and G. Farrel (2000): The shadow economy, Journal of International Affairs, Spring 2000, No. 53/2, pp.64-89. Franz, A. (1983): Wie groß ist die "schwarze" Wirtschaft?, Mitteilungsblatt der Österreichischen Statistischen Gesellschaft, 49/1, pp. 1-6. Feld, Lars, and Bruno S. Frey (2002), The Tax of Authority and the Taxpayer: And Exploratory Analysis, Unpublished Manuscript, University of Zürich, Switzerland Feld, Lars, and Bruno S. Frey (2002a), Trust preeds trust: How Taxpayers are treated, Economics of Governments, 3/1, pp 87-89. Feld, Lars and Claus Larsen (2005): Black Activities in Germany in 2001 and 2004: A Comparison Based on Survey Data, The Rockwool Foundation Research Unit, Copenhagen (DK), 2005. 31.07.07, C:\ShadEconomyCorruption_July2007.doc 58 Frey, Bruno S, (1997), Not just for the Money: An Economic Theory of Personal Motivation, Cheltonham (UK): Edward Elgar Feld, Lars, and Bruno S. Frey, (2005), "Tax Complains as the Result of a Psychological Tax Contract: The Role of Incentives and Responsioe Regulation", Discussion Paper, University of Marburg, Germany Frey, Bruno S. and Hannelore Weck (1983a): "Bureaucracy and the Shadow Economy: A Macro-Approach", in Horst Hanusch (ed.): Anatomy of Government Deficiencies. Berlin: Springer, pp. 89-109. Frey, Bruno S. and Hannelore Weck (1983b): "Estimating the Shadow Economy: A ‘Naive’ Approach," Oxford Economic Papers, 35, pp. 23-44. Frey, Bruno S. and Hannelore Weck-Hannemann (1984): The hidden economy as an "unobserved" variable, European Economic Review, 26/1, pp. 33-53. Frey, Bruno S. and Werner Pommerehne (1984): The hidden economy: State and prospect for measurement, Review of Income and Wealth, 30/1, pp. 1-23. Frey, Bruno S., Weck Hannelore and Werner W. Pommerehne (1982): Has the shadow economy grown in Germany? An exploratory study, Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv, 118/4, pp. 499-524. Friedman, E., Johnson, S., Kaufmann, D. and Zoido-Labton, P. (2000): Dodging the grabbing hand: The determinants of unofficial activity in 69 countries, Journal of Public Economics, 76/4, pp.459-493. Garcia, Gillian (1978): "The currency ratio and the subterranean economy," Financial Analysts Journal, 69:1, pp. 64-66. Gerxhani, Klarita (2003): The informal sector in developed and less-developed countries: A literature survey, Public Choice, 114/3-4, pp.295-318. Giles, David, E.A. (1997a): Causality between the measured and underground economies in New Zealand, Applied Economic Letters 4, pp.63-67. Giles, David, E.A. (1997b): Testing the asymmetry in the measured and underground business cycles in New Zealand, Economic Record 71/1, pp.225-232. Giles, David, E.A. (1999a): Measuring the hidden economy: Implications for econometric modelling, The Economic Journal, 109/456, pp.370-380. Giles, David, E.A. (1999b): Modelling the hidden economy in the tax-gap in New Zealand, Empirical Economics 24/4, pp.621-640. Giles, David, E.A. (1999c): The rise and fall of the New Zealand underground economy: are the reasons symmetric?, Applied Economic Letters 6, pp. 185-189. Giles, David, E.A. and Lindsay M. Tedds (2002): Taxes and the Canadian Underground Economy, Canadian Tax Paper No. 106, Canadian Tax Foundation, Toronto/Ontario. Giles, David, E.A., Tedds, Lindsay, M. and Werkneh, Gugsa (2002): The Canadian underground and measured economies, Applied Economics, 34/4, pp.2347-2352. Gutmann, Pierre M. (1977): "The subterranean economy," Financial Analysts Journal, 34:1, pp. 24-27. Halla, Martin and Friedrich Schneider (2005), "Taxes and Benefits: Two Distuct Options to Cheal on the Stole?", Discussion Paper, Institute of Economics, University of Linz, Linz (Austria) Helberger, Claus and Hans Knepel (1988): "How big is the shadow economy? A re-analysis of the unobservedvariable approach of B. S. Frey and H. Weck-Hannemann", European Economic Journal, 32, pp. 965-76. Hill, Roderick and Muhammed Kabir (1996): Tax rates, the tax mix, and the growth of the underground economy in Canada: What can we infer? Canadian Tax Journal/ Revue Fiscale Canadienne, 44/ 6, pp. 1552-1583. Hindriks, J.; A. Muthoo and M. Keen, 1999, Corruption, extortion and evasion, Journal of Public Economics 74: 395-430. IRS (1979): Estimates of Income Unreported on Individual Tax Reforms, Washington D.C.: Internal revenue service, U.S. Department of the Treasury. IRS (1983): Income Tax Compliance Research: Estimates for 1973-81, Washington D.C.: Internal revenue service, U.S. Department of the Treasury. Isachsen, Arne J. and Steinar Strom (1985): The size and growth of the hidden economy in Norway, Review of Income and Wealth, 31/1, pp. 21-38. Isachsen, Arne J.; Klovland, Jan and Steinar Strom (1982): The hidden economy in Norway, in: Tanzi Vito (ed.): The underground economy in the United States and Abroad, Heath, Lexington, pp. 209-231. Janisch Urban and Dieter Brümmerhoff, (2005) Möglichkeiten und Grenzen der Schätzung der Schattenwirtschaft: Eine kritische Auseinandersetzung mit den Schätzergebnissen der Bargeldmethode nach Schneider, Diskussionspapier, Universität Rostock. 31.07.07, C:\ShadEconomyCorruption_July2007.doc 59 Johnson, Simon; Kaufmann, Daniel; and Andrei Shleifer (1997): The unofficial economy in transition, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Fall, Washington D.C. Johnson, Simon; Kaufmann, Daniel and Pablo Zoido-Lobatón (1998a): Regulatory discretion and the unofficial economy. The American Economic Review, 88/ 2, pp. 387-392. Johnson, Simon; Kaufmann, Daniel and Pablo Zoido-Lobatón (1998b): Corruption, public finances and the unofficial economy. Washington, D.C.: The World Bank, discussion paper. Karmann, Alexander (1986), Monetäre Ansätze zur Erfassung der Schattenwirtschaft: Ein Vergleich verschiedener Messansätze, Kredit und Kapitel 19/3, pp.233-247. Karmann, Alexander (1990), Schattenwirtschaft und ihre Ursachen: Eine empirische Analyse zur Schwarzwirtschaft und Selbstversorgung in der Bundesrepublik Deutschland, Zeitschrift für Wirtschaftsund Sozialwissenschaften (ZWS) 110/3, 1990, pp.185-206. Kaufmann, Daniel and Kaliberda, Aleksander (1996), Integrating the unofficial economy into the dynamics of post socialist economies: A framework of analyses and evidence, in: B. Kaminski (ed.), Economic Transition in Russia and the New States of Eurasia, London: M.E. Sharpe, pp.81-120. Kazemier, Brugt, (2005a), The Undergroud Economy: A Survey of Methods and Estimates Discussion Paper, Statistics Netherlands, Voorburg, Netherlands Kazemier, Brugt, (2005b), Monitorying the Underground Labour Market: What Surveys can do, Discussion Paper, Statistics Netherlands, Voorburg, Netherlands Kirchgaessner, Gebhard (1983): Size and development of the West German shadow economy, 1955-1980, Zeitschrift für die gesamte Staatswissenschaft, 139/2, pp. 197-214. Kirchgaessner, Gebhard (1984): Verfahren zur Erfassung des in der Schattenwirtschaft erarbeiteten Sozialprodukts, Allgemeines Statistisches Archiv, 68/4, pp. 378-405. Kirchler, E.; Maciejovsky, B. and F. Schneider (2002): Everyday representations of tax avoidance, tax evasion and tax flight: Do legal differences matter?, Economic Psychology, 8/3, pp.1-19. Klovland, Jan (1984): "Tax evasion and the demand for currency in Norway and Sweden: Is there a hidden relationship?" Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 86:4, pp. 423-39. Lackó Mária (1996): Hidden economy in East-European countries in international comparison, Laxenburg: International Institute for Applied Systems Analysis (IIASA), working paper. Lackó Mária (1998): The hidden economies of Visegrad countries in international comparison: A household electricity approach, In: Halpern, L. and Wyplosz, Ch. (eds.), Hungary: Towards a market economy, Cambridge (Mass.): Cambridge University Press, p.128-152. Lackó Mária (1999): Hidden economy an unknown quantitiy? Comparative analyses of hidden economies in transition countries in 1989-95, Working paper 9905, Department of Economics, University of Linz, Austria. Lackó Mária (2000), Hidden Economy – An unknown quantity: Comparative analysis of hidden economics in Transition countries 1989-95, Economics of Transition 8/1, pp.117-149. Langfeldt, Enno (1984): The unobserved economy in the Federal Republic of Germany, in: Feige, Edgar L. (ed.): The unobserved economy, Cambridge University Press., pp. 236-260. Lippert, Owen and Michael Walker (eds.) (1997): The Underground Economy: Global Evidences of its Size and Impact, Vancouver, B.C.: The Frazer Institute. Lizzeri, C. (1979): Mezzogiorno in controluce. Enel, Naples. Loayza, N. V. (1996): The economics of the informal sector: a simple model and some empirical evidence from Latin America. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 45, pp. 129-162. MacAfee, Kerrick (1980): A Glimpse of the hidden economy in the national accounts, Economic Trends, 136, pp. 81-87. Marcelli, Enrico A. (2004): Unauthorized Mexican Immigration, the Labour and other Lower-Wage Informal Employment in California, Regional Studies 38/1, pp.1-13. Marcelli, Enrico A., Manuel Pastor jr. and Pascale M. Joassart (1999): Estimating the Effects of Informal Economic Activity: Evidence from Los Angeles County, Journal of Economic Issues 33/3, pp.579-607. Mauleon, Ignacio (1998): Quantitative estimation of the Spanish underground economy, Discussion paper, Department of Economics and History, University of Salamanka, Salamanka, Spain. Méon, Pierre-Guillaume and Khalid Sekkat, 2004, Does the Quality of Institutions Limit the MENA's Integration in the World Economy? The World Economy 27, 9: 1475-1498. 31.07.07, C:\ShadEconomyCorruption_July2007.doc 60 Mogensen, Gunnar V.; Kvist, Hans K.; Körmendi, Eszter and Soren Pedersen (1995): The shadow economy in Denmark 1994: Measurement and results, Study no. 3, Copenhagen: The Rockwool Foundation Research Unit. Morris, B. (1993), Editorial Statement. International Economic Insides, IV, International Statistical Yearbook, Budapest. Mummert, Annette and Friedrich Schneider (2001): The German shadow economy: Parted in a united Germany?, Finanzarchiv, 58/3, pp.260-285. Neck, Reinhard, Hofreither, Markus and Friedrich Schneider (1989): The consequences of progressive income taxation for the shadow economy: Some theoretical considerations, in Boes, Dieter and Felderer, Bernhard (eds.), The political economy of progressive taxation, Heidelberg: Springer publishing company, pp. 149176. O’Higgins, Michael (1989): Assessing the underground economy in the United Kingdom, in: Feige, E.L. (ed.): The underground economies: tax evasion and information distortion, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 175-195. O’Neill, David M. (1983): Growth of the underground economy 1950-81: Some evidence from the current population survey, Study for the Joint Economic Committee, U.S. Congress, Joint Committee Print 98-122, U.S. Gov. Printing Office, Washington. Park, T. (1979): Reconciliation between personal income and taxable income, pp. 1947-77, mimeo, Washington D.C.: Bureau of Economic Analysis. Pelzmann, Linde (1988): Wirtschaftspsychologie. Arbeitslosenforschung, Schattenwirtschaft, Steuerpsychologie. Wien, New York (Springer). Pedersen, Soren (2003): The Shadow Economy in Germany, Great Britain and Scandinavia: A Measurement Based on Questionnaire Service, Study No. 10, The Rockwoll Foundation Research Unit, Copenhagen. Petersen, H.-G.(1982): Size of the public sector, economic growth and the informal economy: Development trends in the Federal Republic of Germany, Review of Income and Wealth, 28/2, pp. 191-215. Pickhardt, Michael and Jose Sarda-Pous (2006): Size and Scope of the Shadow Economy in Germany, Applied Economics 38/4, pp.1707-1713. Pissarides, C. and Weber, G. (1988): An expenditure – based estimate of Britain’s black economy, CLE working paper no. 104, London. Portes, Alejandro (1996): The informal economy, in: Pozo, Susan (ed.): Exploring the underground economy. Kalamazoo, Michigan, pp. 147-165. Pozo, Susan (ed.) (1996): Exploring the Underground Economy: Studies of Illegal and Unreported Activity, Michigan: W.E. Upjohn, Institute for Employment Research. Quirk, Peter, J., (1996), Macroeconomic implications of money laundering, IMF working paper WP/96/66, Washington, D.C. Rogoff, Kenneth, (1998), Blessing or Curse? Foreign and underground demand for euro notes, Economic policy: The European Forum 26, pp. 261-304. Schneider, Friedrich (1986): Estimating the size of the Danish shadow economy using the currency demand approach: An attempt, The Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 88/4, pp. 643-668. Schneider, Friedrich (1994a): Measuring the size and development of the shadow economy. Can the causes be found and the obstacles be overcome? in: Brandstaetter, Hermann, and Güth, Werner (eds.): Essays on Economic Psychology, Berlin, Heidelberg, Springer Publishing Company, pp. 193-212. Schneider, Friedrich (1994b): Can the shadow economy be reduced through major tax reforms? An empirical investigation for Austria, Supplement to Public Finance/ Finances Publiques, 49, pp. 137-152. Schneider, Friedrich (1997): The shadow economies of Western Europe, Journal of the Institute of Economic Affairs, 17/3, pp. 42-48. Schneider, Friedrich (1998a): Further empirical results of the size of the shadow economy of 17 OECD-countries over time, Paper to be presented at the 54. Congress of the IIPF Cordowa, Argentina and discussion paper, Department of Economics, University of Linz, Linz, Austria. Schneider, Friedrich (1998b): Stellt das Anwachsen der Schwarzarbeit eine wirtschaftspolitische Herausforderung dar? Einige Gedanken aus volkswirtschaftlicher Sicht. Linz, Mitteilungen des Instituts für angewandte Wirtschaftsforschung (IAW), I/98, pp. 4-13. Schneider, Friedrich (2000): The increase of the size of the shadow economy of 18 OECD-Countries: Some preliminary explanations, Paper presented at the Annual Public Choice Meeting, March 10-12, 2000, Charleston, S.C. 31.07.07, C:\ShadEconomyCorruption_July2007.doc 61 Schneider, Friedrich (2003): The shadow economy, in: Charles K. Rowley and Friedrich Schneider (eds.), Encyclopedia of Public Choice, Kluwer Academic Publishers, Dordrecht. Schneider, Friedrich (2004): Arbeit im Schatten: "Wo Deutschlands Wirtschaft wirklich wächst.", Wiesbaden, Gabler Verlag Schneider, Friedrich (2005): Shadow Economies around the World: What do we really know?, European Journal of Political Economy, 21/3, pp. 598-642. Schneider, Friedrich (2007): Reducing the Shadow Economy in Germany: A Blessing or a Curse?, Discussion Paper, Department of Economics, University of Linz, Linz. Schneider, Friedrich, Markus F. Hofreither and Reinhard Neck, (1989),The consequences of a changing shadow economy for the official economy: Some empirical results for Austria, in Boes, Dieter and Bernhard Felderer (eds.), The political economy of progressive taxation, Heidelberg: Springer publishing company, pp. 181-211. Schneider, Friedrich and Dominik Enste (2000): Shadow economies: Size, causes, and consequences, The Journal of Economic Literature, 38/1, pp. 77-114. Schneider, F., Enste D. (2002). The Shadow Economy: Theoretical Approaches, Empirical Studies, and Political Implications, Cambridge (UK): Cambridge University Press. Simon, C.B. and A.G. Witte (1982): Beating the system: The underground economy, Boston, (Mas.): Urban House. Smith, J.D (1985): Market motives in the informal economy, in: Gaertner, W. and Wenig, A. (eds.): The economics of the shadow economy, Heidelberg: Springer Publishing Company, pp. 161-177. Smith, Philip (1994): Assessing the size of the underground economy: The statistics Canada perspectives, Canadian Economic Observer, Catalogue No.: 11-010, 3.16-33, at 3.18.Spiro, Peter S. (1993): "Evidence of a Post-GST Increase in the Underground Economy;" Canadian Tax Journal/ Revue Fiscale Canadienne, , 41:2, pp. 247-258. Tanzi, Vito (1980): "The underground economy in the United States: Estimates and implications," Banca Nazionale del Lavoro, 135:4, pp. 427-453. Tanzi, Vito (1982) (ed.): The Underground Economy in the United States and Abroad, Lexington (Mass.), Lexington. Tanzi, Vito (1982): A second (and more skeptical) look at the underground economy in the United States; in: Tanzi, Vito (1982) (ed.): The underground economy in the United States and abroad, Lexington (Mass.), Lexington, pp. 38-56. Tanzi, Vito (1983): "The underground economy in the United States: Annual estimates, 1930-1980," IMF-Staff Papers, 30:2, pp. 283-305. Tanzi, Vito (1986): The underground economy in the United States, Reply to comments by Feige, Thomas, and Zilberfarb. IMF - Staff Papers, 33/ 4, pp. 799-811. Tanzi, Vito (1999): Uses and abuses of estimates of the underground economy, The Economic Journal 109/456, pp.338-340. Thomas, Jim J. (1986): The underground economy in the United States: A comment on Tanzi, IMF-Staff Papers, Vol. 33, No. 4, pp. 782-789. Thomas, Jim J. (1992): Informal Economic Activity, LSE, Handbooks in Economics, London: Harvester Wheatsheaf. Thomas, Jim J. (1999): Quantifying the black economy: ‘Measurement without Theory’ Yet Again?, The Economic Journal 109/456, pp. 381-389. Torgler, Benno, (2002), "Speaking to Theorists and Searching for Facts: Tax Moral and Tax Compliance in Experiments", Journal of Economic Surveys, 16/5, p.657-683. Torgler, Benno and Friedrich Schneider, (2005), "Attitudes Towards Paying Taxes in Austria: An Empirical Analysis", Empirica, pp.204-225. Torgler, Benno and Friedrich Schneider (2007), Shadow Economy, Tax Morale, Governance and Institutional Quality: A Panel Analysis, CREMA Working Paper, Centre for Research in Economics, Management and the Arts, Basel, Switzerland. Weck, Hannelore (1983): Schattenwirtschaft: Eine Möglichkeit zur Einschränkung der öffentlichen Verwaltung? Eine ökonomische Analyze, Bern-Frankfurt. Williams, Colin C. (2004a): Cash-In-Hand Work: The Underground Sector and the Hidden Economy of Favours, Haunddemills/Hampshire (GB), Palgrave McMillan Publishing Company, 2004. Williams, Colin C. (2004b): Geographical Variations in the Nature of Undecleared Work, Geographisca Analer 86/B/3, pp.187-200. 31.07.07, C:\ShadEconomyCorruption_July2007.doc 62 Williams, Colin C. (2005a): Forstering Community Engagement and Tackling Undeclared Work: The Case for an Evidence – Based "joint-up" Public Policy Approach, Regional Studies 39/8, pp.1145-1155. Williams, Colin C. (2005b): Small Business and the Informal Economy: Making the Transition to the Informal Economy – The Evidence Base, Small Business Service, London. Williams, Colin C. (2006): What is to be done about Undecleared Work? Evaluating the Policy Options, Policy and Politics 34/1, pp.91-113. Williams, Colin C. and Jan Windebank (1995): "Black market work in the European Community: Peripheral work for peripheral localities?", International Journal of Urban and Regional Research, 19/1, pp. 23-39. Williams, Colin C. and Jan Windebank (1998): Informal Employment in the Advanced Economies: Implication for Work and Welfare, Routledge, London. Williams, Colin C. and Jan Windebank (2001a): Beyond Profit Motivated Exchange: Some Lessons from the Study of Paid Informal Work, European Urban and Regional Studies 8/1, pp.49-61. Williams, Colin C. and Jan Windebank (2001b): Reconceptualizing Paid Informal Exchance: Some Lessons from English Cities, Environment and Planning A 33/1, pp.121-140. Witte, A.D. (1987): The nature and extend of unreported activity: A survey concentrating on a recent USresearch, in: Alessandrini, S. and Dallago, B. (eds.): The Unofficial Economy: Consequences and perspectives in different economic systems, Gower: Aldershot. Zilberfarb, Ben-Zion (1986): Estimates of the underground economy in the United States, 1930-80. IMF-Staff Papers, 33/ 4, pp. 790-798. 31.07.07, C:\ShadEconomyCorruption_July2007.doc 63